3,580
Views
11
CrossRef citations to date
0
Altmetric
Articles

A change of heart? Analysing stability and change in European party positions

ORCID Icon

Abstract

Political parties are often assumed to be adaptive, strategic organisations that continuously alter their policy positions to maximise electoral support. However, ideological continuity is an integral part of democratic representation as well. How do parties balance these seemingly conflicting roles? This study combines insights from spatial models of elections and cleavage theory to explain stability and change in European party positions. Embracing the multidimensionality of the policy space, I argue that a party’s reputation and durable party-voter linkages constrain positional change on its more salient, primary dimension. Yet, by remaining ideologically true to its supporters’ key concerns, a party can strategically shift on secondary issues outside of its core agenda. Cross-sectional time series analysis of party positions (1999–2019) across fourteen Western European countries confirms this prediction, especially for small to medium-sized and opposition parties. This finding has important implications for our understanding of party strategy and democratic representation.

Supplemental data for this article can be accessed online at: https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2021.1915659 .

Political parties face a challenging trade-off between responsiveness and ideological continuity. They are assumed to be adaptive organisations, continuously – and strategically – updating their platforms to relay the public’s evolving policy preferences and to maximise electoral support (Adams Citation2012; Laver Citation2005). Examples of such party shifts abound. Observers have noted, for example, how the populist radical right has moderated its economic position (De Lange Citation2007) to embrace the welfare chauvinism popular among its supporters (Attewell Citation2021; Magni Citation2020). By contrast, many mainstream right-wing parties have moved in the opposite direction, away from the ideological centre, on cultural issues (Meguid Citation2005) and European integration (Rohrschneider and Whitefield Citation2016) in response to the recent surge of these populist challengers. The British Conservative Party, notoriously divided on the European issue, has also grown more Euroskeptic over time. While Margaret Thatcher’s criticism of the European project once expedited her ouster as Prime Minister and party leader, it was exactly Boris Johnson’s uncompromising pledge to deliver Brexit that propelled him to power in the aftermath of the country’s referendum on EU membership.

However, notwithstanding the dynamic nature of representative democracy, there is ample reason to believe that parties cannot always move freely (Dalton Citation2016; De Sio and Weber Citation2014; Meyer Citation2013; Rovny Citation2015). Coherent, reliable, and distinctive party labels and ideologies are an integral part of representation as well (Mair Citation2008; McKelvey and Ordeshook Citation1986). They provide an important heuristic for vote choice (Downs Citation1957) and party identification (Campbell et al. Citation1960) in a context of uncertainty and limited information. Indeed, contrary to formal theory’s assumption of ‘costless spatial mobility’ (Adams et al. Citation2006), positional change is inherently risky, as it could tarnish a party’s reputation, compromise future coalition negotiations, and alienate voters and activists (Budge Citation1994; Somer-Topcu Citation2009; Tavits Citation2007).

How does a party balance these representative roles and their inherent trade-offs, and, relatedly, when is it more likely to alter its policy appeals? This study brings together insights from spatial models of elections and cleavage theory, two literatures that rarely speak to each other (Rohrschneider Citation2002), to develop a novel framework for understanding stability and change in European party positions. My starting point is the multidimensionality of the policy space in which parties compete (Bakker et al. Citation2012; Rovny and Polk Citation2019; Tavits and Potter Citation2015), which allows me to address the intimate relationship between position and salience (Meguid Citation2005; Wagner Citation2012).

Specifically, I argue that positional stability is likely observed on a dimension that is relatively salient to a party, while policy shifts are confined largely to issues outside of a party’s core agenda. Parties are rooted and invested in, even born out of, underlying social conflicts and come to represent specific issues and voter groups (Lipset and Rokkan Citation1967). As a result, it is especially on its salient, or primary, dimension that a party has a reputation to uphold and defend (Hooghe and Marks Citation2018), and where the inherent risks associated with positional shifts require a proper change of heart. Yet, by remaining ideologically true to its voters’ key concerns, a party will experience fewer constraints when strategically shifting on less salient, secondary issues (Elias et al. Citation2015).

Cross-sectional time series analysis of Chapel Hill Expert Survey (CHES) evaluations of party positions (Bakker et al. Citation2015; Polk et al. Citation2017), covering fourteen Western European countries from 1999 to 2019,Footnote1 confirms that absolute positional change increases as an ideological dimension’s relative salience decreases – and vice versa. The effect is weaker for larger and governing parties, as their increased public scrutiny and executive responsibilities reduce the salience differential between the two dimensions. While the main empirical models employ a continuous ratio measure of economic and cultural dimensional salience based on manifesto data (Volkens et al. Citation2020), additional analyses show similar patterns in position change by party family when dichotomously identifying their respective primary and secondary dimension. Finally, multiple robustness checks, which use alternative model specifications and operationalisations of key variables, lend further support to these findings. This study focuses on Western Europe for data availability, but its results should travel to other established democracies with a history of programmatic politics.

The finding that policy positions are more flexible on a party’s secondary dimension provides an important behavioural prediction that bridges extant literature on party strategy, issue emphasis, political cleavages, and democratic representation, especially in an increasingly multidimensional environment. Above all, it contextualises our spatial assumptions of party strategy – which have been the basis of much of the party competition literature, but which are not always borne out – to reconcile the seeming tension between predicted positional change and observed ideological stability.

Party change and stability

The study of how political parties present themselves to the public, and compete for its vote, has a rich and impressive tradition in the field of comparative politics. Since Downs’ (Citation1957) classic work on the median voter theorem, political scientists have made major advances in understanding how a party locates itself in the political landscape and what factors lead it to alter its ideological position. Spatial models of elections – which view party competition through a positional lens, with parties offering alternative policy proposals to the electorate – have become increasingly sophisticated and comprehensive. Empirical studies now account for a wide range of characteristics, including a party’s office and policy-seeking behaviour, the multifacetedness of voter preferences, and the transformative nature of the policy space (e.g. Adams et al. Citation2006; Budge Citation1994; Hooghe et al. Citation2002; Kriesi et al. Citation2006; Meguid Citation2005).

The causes of party shifts remain contested, however. Which factors explain why a party moves and, equally important, with what magnitude? Extant research suggests that party positions are highly flexible and volatile, as parties respond to a plethora of endogenous and exogenous incentives, such as electoral defeat (Somer-Topcu Citation2009), governing status (Bawn and Somer-Topcu Citation2012), economic conditions (Fenzl Citation2018; Haupt Citation2010), and the policy moves of their competitors (Laver Citation2005). Although diverse, these theories share an implicit belief in the persistence of party change (Adams Citation2012).

For all the attention given to what makes parties move, relatively few studies have been devoted to what makes them stay put (but see Dalton Citation2016; Meyer Citation2013). Yet, it is often acknowledged that position change is inherently risky (Budge Citation1994; Somer-Topcu Citation2009; Tavits Citation2007). Even Downs acknowledged that parties experience serious limitations on their room to manoeuvre, as shifting too much and too often would undermine their ideological integrity and responsibility (Citation1957: 122).

To better understand the constraints on party strategy, this study builds on cleavage theory, which is based on the intuition that party systems reflect the underlying social conflicts in society, shaped – and upset – only by infrequent critical historical junctures. Although not addressing party competition directly (Hooghe and Marks Citation2018) – at least not in the way we typically think of it, as a positional dynamic of action and reaction in a competitive environment – this framework nevertheless raises two valuable insights for the study of party strategic behaviour.

First, it sheds light on the relative durability of party-voter commitments. In their pivotal work, Lipset and Rokkan (Citation1967) trace the origins of party system development to persistent tensions in society between religious, socio-economic, and political groups. These so-called cleavages create solidary communities and lead to the emergence of political parties to express their respective collective interests. The very nature of political conflict then further reinforces and perpetuates an ideological divide’s group identities (Bornschier Citation2010). From this perspective, a party thus enjoys strong linkages with its supporters based on a meaningful and lasting ideological reputation.Footnote2 And we now know that such reputations can be strengthened or revived over time, e.g. through a party’s performance in government, and crucially shape electoral competition (Bélanger and Meguid Citation2008; Budge and Farlie Citation1983). In the words of Lipset and Rokkan, ‘parties do not simply present themselves de novo to the citizen at each election; they each have a history and so have the constellations of alternatives they present the electorate’ (Lipset and Rokkan Citation1967: 2).

Second, although not all of Lipset and Rokkan’s divisions proved equally resilient, or shaped national politics to the same degree, cleavage theory directs our attention to the underlying, multidimensional structure of the political space in Western European democracies (De Vries and Marks Citation2012). And while many studies of party competition today still rely on a unidimensional framework (e.g. Adams et al. Citation2006; Ezrow et al. Citation2011), scholars increasingly assume that a second dimension now structures European politics in addition to an economic left-right divide. This second dimension goes by different labels, but typically encompasses socio-cultural issues, including (though not limited to) immigration, law and order, and environmental politics (Hooghe et al. Citation2002; Kitschelt Citation1994; Kriesi et al. Citation2006).Footnote3 There is thus a growing understanding that ‘multidimensionality cannot be evaded in political practice’ (De Sio and Weber Citation2014: 870).

The above discussion suggests that, in contrast to the strategic interactions in a typical Downsian world, party-voter linkages can be durable and multidimensional. It highlights the causal factors that foster stability in and constraint on a party’s policy platform over multiple election cycles. Whether it is by virtue of deeply-rooted, cross-cutting societal divisions or less distant track records in office, ideological reputations matter and are an integral part of political contestation.

A theory of multidimensional party competition

Returning to our puzzle of representation, how can we bring together spatial modelling and cleavage theory to understand how a party responds to the electorate’s preferences while maintaining ideological continuity? I propose a unified ontology of party competition that sees the Downsian and Rokkanian perspectives not as mutually exclusive but as complementary (Rovny Citation2015). Crucially, its main argument hinges on the notion of multidimensionality and its interaction with salience, the theoretical roots of which can be traced back to cleavage theory (see De Vries and Marks Citation2012; Hooghe and Marks Citation2018).

In a competitive, multidimensional environment, a party encounters ideological dimensions to which it ascribes varying levels of importance. Reminiscent of Schattschneider’s observation, a party is ‘a coalition of inferior interests held together by a dominant interest’ (Citation1960: 69). This relative salience differential is expected to strongly inform a party’s strategic behaviour. While arguably best understood as a continuum, for parsimony, the following theoretical discussion simply distinguishes between a party’s primary and secondary dimension.

A party is expected to be rooted on its more salient, primary dimension. It is connected to a core constituency of voters through a given cleavage, and the durability of this linkage is self-enforcing (Hooghe and Marks Citation2018). Party activists and future leaders are recruited from this very cadre of supporters, they share a common sense of belonging, and are part and parcel of the intra-party decision-making process. What unites the various stakeholders is a set of overarching values. And it is here that a party needs to uphold and defend its reputation. It could do that, for instance, by consistently placing more salience on its related – and presumably competitive – issues (De Sio and Weber Citation2014). Such issue emphases are strongly influenced by a party’s own history and difficult to change (Green-Pedersen and Mortensen Citation2010). This subsequently limits strategic flexibility on its primary dimension. Shifting position tends to be risky and undesirable, as it could be perceived as ‘selling out’ the party’s policy objectives for short-term electoral gains (Adams et al. Citation2006), allowing it at best to seek out local maxima to secure votes (Hooghe and Marks Citation2018).

How does a party behave on its secondary dimension? A party is more invested in its primary divide, but it can neither fully ignore the issues outside of its core agenda nor is it without agency. In fact, recent advances show that the use of a two-dimensional strategy is commonplace in Western Europe, as most parties actively engage with both dimensions of the policy space (Elias et al. Citation2015; Rovny Citation2015). One would expect fewer positional constraints on a party’s secondary dimension, as it is not burdened by long-standing party-voter linkages and its primary reputation is not at stake. This creates room for a party to follow its strategic goals – perhaps even more so when it mutes outside issues (Rovny Citation2012, Citation2013). A range of positional strategies has been identified in the literature, such as moderation, ideological zigzagging, changing course only when faced with electoral losses, or approaching and capitalising on the largest party’s gains (e.g. Laver Citation2005). Together, these strategies serve to maximise electoral support and alleviate internal and external pressures on the party leadership through policy shifts.

The above theoretical framework asserts that the constellation of parties is neither invariably static nor persistently volatile. Rather, I expect that a party’s position will be more stable on its primary than on its secondary dimension. To account for variation over time and between parties, a generalised hypothesis can be formulated in continuous terms:

Hypothesis 1: The greater the relative salience of a dimension to a party, the less flexible its position on that dimension.

Although the hypothesised effect of relative dimensional salience on position change is relevant to all parties, it is worth considering whether any factors might challenge this relationship. A burgeoning literature has investigated the predictors of party strategy, particularly as a product of a party’s organisational goals: vote, office, or policy (Strom Citation1990). While policy-seeking parties are unlikely to change their issue emphases, the same cannot be said for vote and office-seeking parties (Wagner and Meyer Citation2014). Their incentive structures might lead them to opportunistically follow the public’s issue priorities, but it is especially upon achieving their respective goals that pressures will emerge to diversify their policy emphases. First, electorally large parties tend to have broader issue agendas, because their prominence generates more media attention (Brandenburg Citation2002) and undermines attempts to avoid certain issues (Wagner and Meyer Citation2014). Second, parties in government need to enact and implement laws, which make it difficult to maintain a narrow policy agenda (Greene Citation2016). Government experience is also one of the most effective ways for a party to establish a reputation of competence, including on issues outside of its core agenda. Both conditions thus expand a party’s agenda and likely limit the difference between its primary and secondary dimension and, as a result, its effect on positional flexibility.

Hypothesis 2: Electoral strength and government participation diminish the effect of relative dimensional salience on party position change.

Research design

The above hypotheses are tested using pooled data of party positions from 1999 to 2019, measured by the Chapel Hill Expert Survey (Bakker et al. Citation2015; Polk et al. Citation2017), which provides information on the ideological positions of almost one hundred parties on an economic and a cultural dimension across fourteen Western European countriesFootnote4: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.Footnote5

The validity and reliability of party position data have been debated extensively. This study uses expert evaluations because, unfortunately, existing public opinion surveys do not gauge voter perceptions of parties’ multidimensional positions over time. But expert placements have been rigorously tested, cross-validated, and shown to perform as well as, if not better than, other measures, including those based on mass surveys and manifesto data (Marks et al. Citation2007; Steenbergen and Marks Citation2007). Moreover, expert and voter data of party positions are strongly correlated (Dalton and McAllister Citation2015), which suggests that the position shifts estimated here are both reliable and likely picked up by voters. It could be argued that experts are more prone to detect continuity in party platforms, but this is not a concern for this study, as it analyzes positional stability as well as change. By contrast, manifesto data, despite being widely viewed as a valid measure of salience (see below), have received criticism for conflating issue importance with position (Gemenis Citation2013). Nevertheless, various sensitivity analyses confidently show that the main findings of this study are not dependent on any particular measure or data source (see Online appendices 6–10).

I use the absolute difference in the average expert evaluation of a party’s position between waves, both on the economic and the cultural dimension, because my theoretical argument is about ideological flexibility, not direction.Footnote6 That is, the greater a party’s ideological shift from its previous position on a dimension, the higher its score on the dependent variable – regardless of the direction of change. Separate models are specified for each dimension. The histograms for the dependent variables show that, despite their substantive and historical differences, party change is relatively similar across the two dimensions (see Online appendix 3).

Explanatory variables

The main independent variable requires a measure of the relative salience of an ideological dimension to a party. While it is arguably straightforward to identify the primary dimension for some party families, e.g. the radical right, for others the pattern is less clear. What is, for instance, the most salient dimension for the Christian democrats? For that reason, this study uses a quantitative, continuous measure to evaluate dimensional salience. This method is transparent and allows for more variation than a primary-secondary dichotomy.

The most commonly used measure of party-level salience comes from the comparative manifesto project, or MARPOR (Volkens et al. Citation2020). These data classify quasi-sentences of a party’s platform using a coding scheme of 56 categories to gauge the relative emphasis a party places on an issue area, as a percentage of its entire manifesto. It is challenging to reduce issue-level variation to its underlying dimensions, as the policy space in which parties compete is not directly observable. Yet, following the recommendation by Benoit and Laver (Citation2012) to a priori assume the space’s dimensionality, theory can drive our efforts to extract two dimensions from the MARPOR data. For example, issues like protectionism and welfare state expansion can be assigned to the economic dimension, while traditional morality and multiculturalism are classified as cultural. Building on extant work (e.g. Spies and Franzmann Citation2011; Tavits and Potter Citation2015), 42 of the relevant category scores are aggregated into two ideological clusters, consisting of an equal number of issue areas, to assess the relative salience of the economic and cultural dimension (for the full issue categorisation, see Online appendix 2).Footnote7

A ratio between the two dimensions captures the relative salience at the time of the most recent national election and ranges from 1 (manifesto solely about economy) to −1 (all culture). For example, if Party A devotes 70% of its manifesto to the economy and 30% to cultural issues, it would receive a score of 0.40, which, because it is positive, indicates that the economy is relatively more salient to the party than the cultural dimension.Footnote8 Finally, to account for systemic salience, the party system average is subtracted from the above score (excluding a party’s own salience score), as a party’s agenda is partly shaped by the actions of competing parties (Green-Pedersen and Mortensen Citation2010). shows the distribution of relative salience by party family. As one might expect, radical right, green, and confessional parties emphasise the cultural dimension, whereas the economy takes precedence for most major party families as well as the radical left.

Figure 1. Relative dimensional salience by party family.

Figure 1. Relative dimensional salience by party family.

Additional variables are included that could directly affect party position change. Both a party’s electoral strength and age may affect position change, as larger and older parties tend to have more established reputations that are difficult to change (Dalton Citation2016; Tavits and Potter Citation2015). Measures are included that report a party’s vote share in the most recent national election and its age, respectively. And an indicator variable records whether a party was in government during the previous wave. Wielding executive power might, on the one hand, reduce policy shifts, as a party has little incentive to alter the status quo when it enjoys frequent access to government (Schumacher et al. Citation2013). Others, by contrast, have argued that being in government is associated with larger positional change, as these parties must tailor policies to changing socio-economic conditions (e.g. Somer-Topcu Citation2009). Next, an extensive literature exists on the relationship between party organisation and positional change. That is, leadership-dominated parties are assumed to be more strategic, office-seeking, and ideologically flexible than organisations in which the balance of power is tipped in favour of policy-seeking activists (Koedam Citation2019; Schumacher and Giger Citation2018). A control variable indicates the degree to which the leadership is dominant in setting the party’s policy agenda (Rohrschneider and Whitefield Citation2012). The models also control for a party’s ideological extremism on each dimension, as parties operating on the fringes of the political spectrum might enjoy more room to manoeuvre but, conversely, could also have more rigid, policy-oriented appeals (Adams et al. Citation2006). Lastly, the effective number of electoral parties is included (Gallagher and Mitchell Citation2005; Laakso and Taagepera Citation1979), as the degree of party system fragmentation likely affects a party’s ideological space and strategic opportunities. A complete overview of all variables, their operationalisation, and descriptive statistics and correlations are available in Online appendices 1–5.

Analysis

This study employs a cross-sectional time series analysis with party-wave as the unit of observation. The dependent variables are first-differenced, tracking party change on each dimension from one survey year to the next, to analyse the direct effect of a dimension’s relative salience level on Y. The generalised model can be specified as follows:|Δ position(i,t)|=α+β1 salience(i,t)+β2 covariates(i,t)+β3 interactions(i,t)+ϵ(i,t)where the dependent variable is the absolute positional shift of party i on either the economic or the cultural dimension at t compared to t−1; the key independent variable is a party’s relative dimensional salience at time t (measured at the most recent national election); the covariates include a party’s vote share, government participation, age, leadership dominance, ideological extremism, and the effective number of parties, all of which vary over time, with the exception of party organisation; and the interaction terms model the effect of relative salience on position change by electoral strength and government status, respectively. Note that while the dependent variables are differenced, the main independent variable is not. The model includes the level of a dimension’s salience (t) to explain party change (tt−1), not the difference in salience between t and t−1. After all, a party is expected to move more on a dimension that is less salient, even when the relative salience of that dimension does not change.Footnote9

Tests show that the residuals at time t−1 are a good predictor of the residuals at t, indicating a problem with serial correlation, specifically of the panel-specific AR(1) type. Instead of using the traditional correction that leads one to include a lagged dependent variable on the right-hand side, a Prais-Winsten solution is used, as the former approach has been shown to produce bias and wash out the effect of the variables that are of theoretical interest (Plümper et al. Citation2005).Footnote10 Unexpectedly, given the multitude of parties, nested within countries, the data also show panel-level heteroscedasticity, so corrected standard errors are used.

confirms this study’s main hypothesis that the relative salience of an ideological dimension predicts a party’s positional shifts. Models 1 and 2 – which report the results without and with the interaction terms, respectively – show that the more salient the economic dimension, the less likely a party is to change position on that dimension. On the cultural dimension, by contrast, this finding is reversed (Models 3 and 4): as the salience ratio increases, and the cultural dimension thus becomes relatively less important than the economy, position change is more likely. The relevant coefficient estimates are statistically significant across the board, but do have smaller magnitudes on the cultural dimension, which likely reflects its inherent complexity compared to economic left-right (Rovny and Polk Citation2019). It combines a diverse set of policy issues on which parties could take inconsistent positions. Populist radical right parties and voters, for example, increasingly combine largely conservative attitudes with more modern, progressive views on morality issues (Lancaster Citation2020), which would produce a more muddied image of dimensional position change.

Table 1. Analysis of party position change, 1999–2019.

Moving on to the covariates, government parties are less likely to change position, which suggests that they are constrained by their executive functions and do not try to upend the status quo. As expected, the positive estimate for leadership-dominated parties is particularly strong and conforms to extant work on the importance of party organisation for party strategy (e.g. Schumacher and Giger Citation2018). The statistical significance and sign of the other variables – vote share, party age, extremism, and the effective number of parties – vary by dimension. This could be an indication that there are substantial differences between those parties for whom the economic dimension is more salient and those who primarily emphasise cultural issues (see also Tavits and Potter Citation2015). While the bivariate correlations between these variables are low (see Online appendix 5), and new parties are thus not necessarily smaller or more radical, this is nevertheless an important observation that will be explored in more detail below.

The results reported in offer a first indication of the relationships between the included variables, but the preferred way to interpret especially the interaction terms is by means of marginal effects plots. Not only does this allow us to examine directly the conditional relationship of relative dimensional salience on party position change at different values of the moderating variables, the greater magnitude of relative salience’s estimates in Models 2 and 4 (compared to the baseline specifications) indicate that we need to account for these interactions to fully understand their intricate relationships.

To reiterate, the expectation is that electoral strength and government participation weaken the relationship between relative salience and positional flexibility. confirms this prediction with regard to vote share. On the economic dimension, the marginal effect of relative salience is negative as before, but its magnitude declines as a party’s electoral strength increases.Footnote11 In fact, the effect is no longer statistically significant for parties with a vote share greater than 15%, when the 95% confidence interval includes the null. Similarly, the positive coefficient estimate for relative salience on the cultural dimension decreases in size, albeit slightly, before becoming statistically indistinguishable from zero for larger parties (around 13%). Thus, for electorally strong parties, which have broader issue agendas that encompass both ideological dimensions, relative salience no longer predicts party change. Nevertheless, given that about two thirds of the included party-wave observations fall below these electoral thresholds, the reported relationships remain meaningful and valid for the vast majority of parties.

Figure 2. Marginal effect of relative salience on party position change by electoral strength.

Figure 2. Marginal effect of relative salience on party position change by electoral strength.

Next, plots the marginal effect of relative salience by government status.Footnote12 As expected, on both dimensions, the estimates converge on zero once a party enters government. On the economic dimension, the marginal effect loses half of its magnitude compared to opposition parties, whereas on the cultural dimension it is no longer statistically significant. Enjoying government status thus comes at a cost. When taking on executive responsibilities, a party is forced to address a wide variety of issues, including on its less salient dimension, and it concedes at least partial control over its own agenda. This constrains its behaviour and limits its ability to adopt tailored strategies on individual dimensions.

Figure 3. Marginal effect of relative salience on party position change by government participation.

Figure 3. Marginal effect of relative salience on party position change by government participation.

Taken together, these findings provide strong and consistent support for the main hypotheses of this study. And the magnitude of the presented effect sizes is substantively meaningful, individually approximating up to one third of a standard deviation of the dependent variables. To further interpret the results, consider the following illustrative examples. Between 2006 and 2010, the Dutch Partij voor de Vrijheid moved from a strongly rightist position to the near centre on the economic dimension – a shift far bigger than its cumulative position changes over multiple waves on its more salient cultural dimension (2006–2019). In the midst of Europe’s financial crisis, and presumably knowing that economic attitudes do predict its electoral support (Attewell Citation2021), this was likely a strategic decision – one also adopted by other radical right parties. For instance, similarly large economic shifts were made by Front National (France) and Freiheitliche Partei Österreichs (Austria), parties for whom the cultural dimension was considerably more salient than the rest of the party system. By contrast, the smallest positional changes between waves on the economic dimension were made either by established parties like Partido Social Democrata (Portugal) and Partido Popular (Spain), outspoken left-wing parties like Enhedslisten (Denmark) and Kommounistikó Kómma Elládas (Greece), or both, e.g. in the case of Socialdemokraterna (Sweden) and Partij van de Arbeid (the Netherlands).

Multiple robustness checks produce strongly similar results and further corroborate the above findings (see Online appendices 6–10). The negative relationship between relative dimensional salience and party position change is confirmed in additional tests that include: (1) a dependent variable which uses positional data derived from the manifesto project, specifically Lowe et al.’s (Citation2011) log transformation; (2) an alternative, expert-level evaluation of economic and cultural salience, the key independent variable, as reported by CHES; (3) a combined ratio measure of position change similar to the operationalisation of relative salience; (4) an examination of long-term party change over more than one wave, i.e. t compared to t−2, to rule out that the results are driven by short-term zigzagging; (5) a lagged measure of vote share to confirm that it gauges a party’s electoral strength, not the appeal of its most recent positional shift; (6) country and survey wave fixed effects and (7) an analysis of positional shifts on individual economic and cultural policy issues. The latter suggests that salience similarly affects party change at lower levels of aggregation.

A dichotomous measure of dimensional salience

So far, this study’s focus has been on a continuous measure of relative dimensional salience. This is a direct test of the theoretical argument with immediate implications for spatial models of elections. We can study this relationship further, however, by treating relative salience dichotomously in order to identify a party’s primary and secondary dimension. This operationalisation speaks particularly well to cleavage theory and a growing literature on second dimension politics, which tend to study political dynamics at the level of the party family (e.g. Elias et al. Citation2015; Hooghe and Marks Citation2018; Kriesi et al. Citation2006). Although a binary classification is less fine-grained, it provides an alternative lens for exploring patterns in party behaviour across different ideological dimensions.

describes party position change on the economic dimension by party family.Footnote13 It distinguishes between those families for whom the economy is a primary versus a secondary dimension, based on their average score on the relative salience measure employed in the main analysis. Given that this variable runs from −1 to 1, 0 is used as a logical cut-off point. A clear pattern emerges from this plot. The three party families that have a negative relative salience value (i.e. green, confessional, and radical right parties), and for whom the economic dimension is thus secondary, substantially shift their ideological positions. Conversely, the party families for whom this is their primary, most salient dimension (i.e. Christian democrat, radical left, liberal, conservative, regionalist, and socialist parties), as exemplified by their positive salience score, see decidedly less change. This is true when looking at the median value as well as the overall distribution of position change for each party family. So, despite the tremendous internal variation within each party family – e.g. in terms of electoral strength, government status, or even the magnitude of the salience differential between the dimensions – we observe a stark contrast in party behaviour across the primary and secondary dimension.

Figure 4. Party position change by party family, economic dimension.

Figure 4. Party position change by party family, economic dimension.

Next, in order to directly compare these findings, we can add position change on the cultural dimension (see ). Several important conclusions can be drawn from this plot. First and foremost, almost all party families shift position more on their secondary dimension. For five party families for whom the economic dimension is primary, the median and overall distribution of position change on the cultural dimension are considerably higher. In fact, more than 75% of Christian democrat and liberal parties’ cultural position changes are larger in magnitude than their median economic shift (i.e. the 25th percentile is greater than the 50th percentile, respectively). Similarly, the median cultural shift made by radical left and conservative parties is almost twice the size of their median shift on the economic dimension. For the party families for whom the economy is secondary, the opposite tends to be true. The overall pattern is less pronounced, which again speaks to the relative complexity of the cultural dimension, but especially confessional and radical right parties’ economic shifts are significantly more substantial than the median value of their cultural changes. The picture is less unambiguous for the socialists and greens, perhaps exemplifying the particular challenges that these parties face when balancing their economic and cultural appeals (Abou-Chadi and Wagner Citation2020).

Figure 5. Party position change by party family, economic & cultural dimension.

Figure 5. Party position change by party family, economic & cultural dimension.

Finally, it is worth highlighting the differences both within and between party families. First, some parties, such as the Christian democrats, have significantly more stable platforms than their competitors. This is not simply a divide between mainstream and challenger parties (e.g. the greens and the radical right), as for instance socialist parties have comparatively flexible positions as well. Second, the interquartile ranges shown in suggest that considerable variation exists within each party family. This is in line with my previous findings and confirms the importance of individual-level characteristics for party strategy, such as government participation and leadership dominance.

Discussion

Every political party faces cross-pressures to respond to citizens’ evolving preferences while simultaneously maintaining ideological continuity. To evaluate representative democracy in Western Europe, it is important to analyse when and how parties alter and adapt their policy platforms. This study presents a novel lens to better understand how these demands shape party behaviour. It brings together insights from spatial models of elections (e.g. Adams Citation2012; Downs Citation1957) and cleavage theory (e.g. Lipset and Rokkan Citation1967; Hooghe and Marks Citation2018) to explain stability and change in parties’ multidimensional ideological positions. By embracing the multidimensionality of contemporary politics in Western Europe, this study provides a set of predictions about where the strategic actions of parties, as described by spatial modellers, are more likely to be observed.

A party faces constraints especially when shifting its established agenda (Hooghe and Marks Citation2018; Meyer Citation2013), as its ongoing commitments to its core agenda make change undesirable and risky. This leads them to actively engage with their secondary dimension (Elias et al. Citation2015). Conversely, strategic policy shifts, which have been the focus of much of the party competition literature (see Adams Citation2012), are particularly likely on issues less salient to a party. Certainly, parties can and do change position on their core dimension (see, e.g. Adams et al. Citation2006; Ezrow et al. Citation2011), but such (potentially high profile) policy shifts are relatively less common and auspicious. The reported findings convincingly confirm this relationship between dimensional salience and party change, both when treating dimensional salience continuously and dichotomously, as a binary distinction between a party’s primary and secondary dimension. Furthermore, the results are robust to multiple alternative operationalisations.

These findings have several important implications and contribute, directly or indirectly, to a variety of literatures. In addition to those already mentioned – spatial modelling and cleavage theory – its findings relate to extant research on, among others, salience (Bélanger and Meguid Citation2008), issue ownership (Budge and Farlie Citation1983; Petrocik Citation1996) and entrepreneurship (Hobolt and De Vries Citation2015) and niche parties (Meguid Citation2005).

This study also makes a methodological contribution to an ongoing debate about the measurement of parties’ programmatic appeals (Marks et al. Citation2007; Steenbergen and Marks Citation2007). By integrating both expert surveys and manifesto data, it provides one way in which the respective strengths of each methodology can be optimised. It further develops a novel measure of relative dimensional salience that can be used in future research on party strategy.

Additional research is needed, however. For instance, how does public opinion shape the salience of an ideological divide? And do voters pick up on parties’ positional shifts, large or small, on both dimensions? While this study is not the first to establish the connection between position and salience, it provides a new avenue to analyse their intricate relationship. Yes, a party might emphasise the issues popular among both its supporters and the general public to ‘yield’ greater voter support (De Sio and Weber Citation2014) – and mute those that could harm its electoral fortunes (Rovny Citation2012, Citation2013) – but the appeal of the theoretical argument presented here is that it does not do away with the positional dynamics of party competition altogether. Position change is risky, but that does not mean that a party will accept the status quo, especially on issues outside of its core agenda. Rather, altering one’s positional appeals could change its electoral fate. As such, this perspective can better explain how party strategies might vary over time, as parties respond to the changing preferences of both their voters and their competitors.

Crucially, although the relationship between positional flexibility and dimensional salience is now well established, no theoretical argument was presented about the direction of these policy shifts. Do parties use outside issues to amplify their ideological distinctiveness or do they pursue a median voter strategy on their secondary dimension in an attempt to appeal to more centrist voters? They could, for instance, employ policy-based cues to chase undecided swing voters, as opposed to the emotional appeals used to mobilise loyal supporters (Rohrschneider Citation2002). Or perhaps they converge on the position of their main rival? Indeed, we have seen that mainstream right parties, such as the conservatives and Christian democrats, have done exactly that by approaching radical right challengers on the cultural dimension. Regardless, while some have concluded that policy shifts are generally more appropriate on the economic dimension (Tavits Citation2007), this study suggests that what is deemed pragmatic or principled varies by party. We do not have all the answers yet – and better data on particularly voters’ multidimensional attitudes are much needed – but this study provides a first step in a broader research agenda on multidimensional representation.

Supplemental material

fwep_a_1915659_sm5950.pdf

Download PDF (786.2 KB)

Acknowledgments

This article benefitted greatly from the comments of numerous colleagues. While I cannot mention all of them here, I am incredibly grateful for their feedback. In particular, I want to thank Gary Marks, Liesbet Hooghe, Milada Vachudova, Jonathan Polk, Jan Rovny, Marco Steenbergen, Simon Bornschier, Jim Adams and the anonymous reviewers for their help and advice.

Disclosure statement

No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author.

Additional information

Notes on contributors

Jelle Koedam

Jelle Koedam is a postdoctoral researcher in the Department of Political Science, University of Zurich. His research focuses on political parties and democratic representation, in particular the multidimensionality of electoral politics. [koedam@ipz.uzh.ch]

Notes

1 The included countries are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom.

2 This should be true even in an era of cleavage decline (Thomassen Citation2005), party detachment (Mair Citation2008), and increased issue voting (Green-Pedersen and Mortensen Citation2010). As Hooghe and Marks (Citation2018) note, cleavage voting is not all or nothing. Rather, dealignment is coupled with realignment, as can be seen when explaining support for green and radical right parties.

3 It is important to note that the cleavage structure of party competition is ultimately national in nature. Additional dimensions may come to shape politics in a given country, such as the center-periphery cleavage. In countries like Belgium and the United Kingdom, for instance, territorial issues have increasingly come to shape domestic politics. However, this study’s focus is on the two dimensions that can be found in every Western European country, namely the economic and the cultural axes of contestation, and its generalised prediction should hold regardless of the national context.

4 The variables, lrecon and galtan, map a party’s ideological position on economic and socio-cultural issues (both ranging from 0 to 10), respectively. GAL-TAN stands for Green/Alternative/Libertarian-Traditional/Authoritarian/Nationalist.

5 The data span six separate waves (1999, 2002, 2006, 2010, 2014 and 2019), though not all parties are consistently included across all waves due to data availability.

6 A differenced dependent variable has the added advantage of taking care of potential heteroskedasticity and unit effects, as it levels variation in the intercepts.

7 Although the employed classification scheme is as inclusive as possible, not all of the 56 categories can reasonable be described as economic or cultural, e.g. federalism or political corruption. These issue areas are therefore excluded from the analysis.

8 ( 70 30 ) ( 70 + 30 ) = 0.40

9 Indeed, extant research suggests that both the party system agenda and individual parties’ issue emphases are characterised by inertia (Green-Pedersen and Mortensen Citation2010).

10 Like most research on party competition, this data set is of the N > T variety, meaning that there are fewer time points than panels, which could lead to optimistic estimates. For that reason, multiple alternative specifications are tried out to check the robustness of this model.

11 The other interacting variable, government status, is set at 0 (i.e. not in government).

12 Vote share is held constant at its median (9.8).

13 All parties but those with a vote share greater than 15% are included here, as it was established in the previous analyses that relative dimensional salience no longer affects position change beyond this threshold. The agrarian/center family is omitted, because not enough parties are included to plot their distribution.

References

  • Abou-Chadi, Tarik, and Markus Wagner (2020). ‘Electoral Fortunes of Social Democratic Parties: Do Second Dimension Positions Matter?’, Journal of European Public Policy, 27:2, 246–72.
  • Adams, James (2012). ‘Causes and Electoral Consequences of Party Policy Shifts in Multiparty Elections: Theoretical Results and Empirical Evidence’, Annual Review of Political Science, 15:1, 401–19.
  • Adams, James, Michael Clark, Lawrence Ezrow, and Garrett Glasgow (2006). ‘Are Niche Parties Fundamentally Different from Mainstream Parties? The Causes and the Electoral Consequences of Western European Parties’ Policy Shifts, 1976-1998’, American Journal of Political Science, 50:3, 513–29.
  • Attewell, David (2021). ‘Deservingness Perceptions, Welfare State Support and Vote Choice in Western Europe’, West European Politics 44:3, 611–34.
  • Bakker, Ryan, Catherine de Vries, Erica Edwards, Liesbet Hooghe, Seth Jolly, Gary Marks, Jonathan Polk, Jan Rovny, Marco Steenbergen, and Milada Anna Vachudova (2015). ‘Measuring Party Positions in Europe: The Chapel Hill Expert Survey Trend File, 1999-2010’, Party Politics, 21:1, 143–152.
  • Bakker, Ryan, Seth Jolly, and Jonathan Polk (2012). ‘Complexity in the European Party Space: Exploring Dimensionality with Experts’, European Union Politics, 13:2, 219–45.
  • Bawn, Kathleen, and Zeynep Somer-Topcu (2012). ‘Government versus Opposition at the Polls: How Governing Status Affects the Impact of Policy Positions’, American Journal of Political Science, 56:2, 433–46.
  • Bélanger, Éric, and Bonnie M. Meguid (2008). ‘Issue Salience, Issue Ownership, and Issue-Based Vote Choice’, Electoral Studies, 27:3, 477–91.
  • Benoit, Kenneth, and Michael Laver (2012). ‘The Dimensionality of Political Space: Epistemological and Methodological Considerations’, European Union Politics, 13:2, 194–218.
  • Bornschier, Simon (2010). Cleavage Politics and the Populist Right: The New Cultural Conflict in Western Europe. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.
  • Brandenburg, Heinz (2002). ‘Who Follows Whom? The Impact of Parties on Media Agenda Formation in the 1997 British General Election Campaign’, Harvard International Journal of Press/Politics, 7:3, 34–54.
  • Budge, Ian (1994). ‘A New Spatial Theory of Party Competition: Uncertainty, Ideology and Policy Equilibria Viewed Comparatively and Temporally’, British Journal of Political Science, 24:4, 443–67.
  • Budge, Ian, and Dennis Farlie (1983). ‘Party Competition: Selective Emphasis or Direct Confrontation? An Alternative View with Data’, in Hans Daalder and Peter Mair (eds.), Western European Party Systems: Continuity and Change. London: Sage, 267–305.
  • Campbell, Angus, Philip E. Converse, Warren E. Miller, and Donald E. Stokes (1960). The American Voter. New York: Wiley.
  • Dalton, Russell J. (2016). ‘Stability and Change in Party Issue Positions: The 2009 and 2014 European Elections’, Electoral Studies, 44, 525–34.
  • Dalton, Russell J., and Ian McAllister (2015). ‘Random Walk or Planned Excursion? Continuity and Change in Left-Right Positions of Political Parties’, Comparative Political Studies, 48:6, 759–87.
  • De Lange, Sarah L. (2007). ‘A New Winning Formula? The Programmatic Appeal of the Radical Right’, Party Politics, 13:4, 411–35.
  • De Sio, Lorenzo, and Till Weber (2014). ‘Issue Yield: A Model of Party Strategy in Multidimensional Space’, American Political Science Review, 108:4, 870–85.
  • De Vries, Catherine E., and Gary Marks (2012). ‘The Struggle over Dimensionality: A Note on Theory and Empirics’, European Union Politics, 13:2, 185–93.
  • Downs, Anthony (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper.
  • Elias, Anwen, Edina Szöcsik, and Christina I. Zuber (2015). ‘Position, Selective Emphasis and Framing: How Parties Deal with a Second Dimension in Competition’, Party Politics, 21:6, 839–50.
  • Ezrow, Lawrence, Catherine De Vries, Marco Steenbergen, and Erica Edwards (2011). ‘Mean Voter Representation and Partisan Constituency Representation: Do Parties Respond to the Mean Voter Position or to Their Supporters?’, Party Politics, 17:3, 275–301.
  • Fenzl, Michele (2018). ‘Income Inequality and Party (de)Polarisation’, West European Politics, 41:6, 1262–81.
  • Gallagher, Michael, and Paul Mitchell (2005). The Politics of Electoral Systems. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Gemenis, Kostas (2013). ‘What to Do (and Not to Do) with the Comparative Manifestos Project Data’, Political Studies, 61:1_suppl, 3–23.
  • Giger, Nathalie, and Gijs Schumacher (2015). ‘Integrated Party Organization Dataset’, Harvard Dataverse. Retrieved from https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/PE8TWP
  • Greene, Zachary (2016). ‘Competing on the Issues: How Experience in Government and Economic Conditions Influence the Scope of Parties’ Policy Messages’, Party Politics, 22:6, 809–22.
  • Green-Pedersen, Christoffer, and Peter B. Mortensen (2010). ‘Who Sets the Agenda and Who Responds to It in the Danish Parliament? A New Model of Issue Competition and Agenda-Setting’, European Journal of Political Research, 49:2, 257–81.
  • Haupt, Andrea B. (2010). ‘Parties’ Responses to Economic Globalization’, Party Politics, 16:1, 5–27.
  • Hobolt, Sara B., and Catherine E. De Vries (2015). ‘Issue Entrepreneurship and Multiparty Competition’, Comparative Political Studies, 48:9, 1159–85.
  • Hooghe, Liesbet, and Gary Marks (2018). ‘Cleavage Theory Meets Europe’s Crises: Lipset, Rokkan, and the Transnational Cleavage’, Journal of European Public Policy, 25:1, 109–35.
  • Hooghe, Liesbet, Gary Marks, and Carole J. Wilson (2002). ‘Does Left/Right Structure Party Positions on European Integration?’, Comparative Political Studies, 35:8, 965–89.
  • Kitschelt, Herbert (1994). The Transformation of European Social Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Koedam, Jelle (2019). ‘Who’s at the Helm? When Party Organization Matters for Party Strategy’, Journal of Elections, Public Opinion, and Parties. Retrieved from https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1080/17457289.2019.1655647
  • Kriesi, Hanspeter, Edgar Grande, Romain Lachat, Martin Dolezal, Simon Bornschier, and Timotheos Frey (2006). ‘Globalization and the Transformation of the National Political Space: Six European Countries Compared’, European Journal of Political Research, 45:6, 921–56.
  • Laakso, Markku, and Rein Taagepera (1979). ‘Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe’, Comparative Political Studies, 12:1, 3–27.
  • Lancaster, Caroline M. (2020). ‘Not so Radical after All: Ideological Diversity among Radical Right Supporters and Its Implications’, Political Studies, 68:3, 600–16.
  • Laver, Michael (2005). ‘Policy and the Dynamics of Political Competition’, American Political Science Review, 99:2, 263–81.
  • Lipset, Seymour M., and Stein Rokkan (1967). Party Systems and Voter Alignments: Cross-National Perspectives. New York: The Free Press.
  • Lowe, Will, Kenneth Benoit, Slava Mikhaylov, and Michael Laver (2011). ‘Scaling Policy Preferences from Coded Political Texts’, Legislative Studies Quarterly, 36:1, 123–55.
  • Magni, Gabriele (2020). ‘Economic Inequality, Immigrants and Selective Solidarity: From Perceived Lack of Opportunity to in-Group Favoritism’, British Journal of Political Science. Retrieved from https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123420000046
  • Mair, Peter (2008). ‘The Challenge to Party Government’, West European Politics, 31:1-2, 211–34.
  • Marks, Gary, Liesbet Hooghe, Marco R. Steenbergen, and Ryan Bakker (2007). ‘Crossvalidating Data on Party Positioning on European Integration’, Electoral Studies, 26:1, 23–38.
  • McKelvey, Richard D., and Peter C. Ordeshook (1986). ‘Information, Electoral Equilibria, and the Democratic Ideal’, The Journal of Politics, 48:4, 909–37.
  • Meguid, Bonnie M. (2005). ‘Competition between Unequals: The Role of Mainstream Party Strategy in Niche Party Success’, American Political Science Review, 99:3, 347–59.
  • Meyer, Thomas M. (2013). Constraints on Party Policy Change. Colchester: ECPR Press.
  • Petrocik, John R. (1996). ‘Issue Ownership in Presidential Elections, with a 1980 Case Study’, American Journal of Political Science, 40:3, 825–50.
  • Plümper, Thomas, Vera E. Troeger, and Philip Manow (2005). ‘Panel Data Analysis in Comparative Politics: Linking Method to Theory’, European Journal of Political Research, 44:2, 327–54.
  • Polk, Jonathan, et al. (2017). ‘Explaining the Salience of Anti-Elitism and Reducing Political Corruption for Political Parties in Europe with the 2014 Chapel Hill Expert Survey Data’, Research and Politics, 4:1, 1–9.
  • Rohrschneider, Robert (2002). ‘Mobilizing versus Chasing: How Do Parties Target Voters in Election Campaigns’, Electoral Studies, 21:3, 367–82.
  • Rohrschneider, Robert, and Stephen Whitefield (2012). The Strain of Representation: How Parties Represent Diverse Voters in Western and Eastern Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Rohrschneider, Robert, and Stephen Whitefield (2016). ‘Responding to Growing European Union-Skepticism? The Stances of Political Parties toward European Integration in Western and Eastern Europe following the Financial Crisis’, European Union Politics, 17:1, 138–61.
  • Rovny, Jan (2012). ‘Who Emphasizes and Who Blurs? Party Strategies in Multidimensional Competition’, European Union Politics, 13:2, 269–92.
  • Rovny, Jan (2013). ‘Where Do Radical Right Parties Stand? Position Blurring in Multidimensional Competition’, European Political Science Review, 5:1, 1–26.
  • Rovny, Jan (2015). ‘Riker and Rokkan: Remarks on the Strategy and Structure of Party Competition’, Party Politics, 21:6, 912–8.
  • Rovny, Jan, and Jonathan Polk (2019). ‘New Wine in Old Bottles: Explaining the Dimensional Structure of European Party Systems’, Party Politics, 25:1, 12–24.
  • Schattschneider, Elmer E. (1960). The Semisovereign People. A Realist’s View of Democracy in America. Hinsdale: Dryden Press.
  • Schumacher, Gijs, Catherine E. De Vries, and Barbara Vis (2013). ‘Why Do Parties Change Position? Party Organization and Environmental Incentives’, The Journal of Politics, 75:2, 464–77.
  • Schumacher, Gijs, and Nathalie Giger (2018). ‘Do Leadership-Dominated Parties Change More?’, Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties, 28:3, 349–60.
  • Somer-Topcu, Zeynep (2009). ‘Timely Decisions: The Effects of Past National Elections on Party Policy Change’, The Journal of Politics, 71:1, 238–48.
  • Spies, Dennis, and Simon T. Franzmann (2011). ‘A Two-Dimensional Approach to the Political Opportunity Structure of Extreme Right Parties in Western Europe’, West European Politics, 34:5, 1044–69.
  • Steenbergen, Marco, and Gary Marks (2007). ‘Evaluating Expert Judgments’, European Journal of Political Research, 46:3, 347–66.
  • Strom, Kaare (1990). ‘A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties’, American Journal of Political Science, 34:2, 565–98.
  • Tavits, Margit (2007). ‘Principle vs. Pragmatism: Policy Shifts and Political Competition’, American Journal of Political Science, 51:1, 151–65.
  • Tavits, Margit, and Joshua D. Potter (2015). ‘The Effect of Inequality and Social Identity on Party Strategies’, American Journal of Political Science, 59:3, 744–58.
  • Thomassen, Jacques (2005). The European Voter. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Volkens, Andrea, et al. (2020). ‘The Manifesto Data Collection’, Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung. Retrieved from https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.25522/manifesto.mpds.2020b
  • Wagner, Markus (2012). ‘When Do Parties Emphasise Extreme Positions? How Strategic Incentives for Policy Differentiation Influence Issue Importance’, European Journal of Political Research, 51:1, 64–88.
  • Wagner, Markus, and Thomas M. Meyer (2014). ‘Which Issues Do Parties Emphasise? Salience Strategies and Party Organisation in Multiparty Systems’, West European Politics, 37:5, 1019–45.