Skip to main content

The Ideological Incentive for Campaigning on Corruption Issues: The Two-Party Case

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Corruption, Ideology, and Populism
  • 657 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter the theoretical model employed to identify the relationship between ideological positions and the incentives of a party to campaign on political corruption is introduced for a two-party system. The conclusion is that the more parties or candidates present a similar policy programme, the more such incentives grow. The empirical implications of the model are then controlled for by focusing on three countries: a ‘pure’ two-party system like the United States, and Italy and Japan during their respective long periods of no-cabinet alternation. Although these two latter democracies cannot be considered as two-party systems, they can be analysed using the theoretical framework proposed. Moreover, focusing on these two countries allows deeper investigation of the negative side of valence campaigning on corruption by a perennial opposition party.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

References

  • Abney, R., Adams, J., Clark, M., Easton, M., Ezrow, L., Kosmidis, S., et al. (2013). When Does Valence Matter? Heightened Valence Effects for Governing Parties During Election Campaigns. Party Politics, 19(1), 61–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abramowitz, A. I. (2011). The Disappearing Center: Engaged Citizens, Polarization, and American Democracy. Yale: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., & Merrill, S. (2009). Policy-Seeking Parties in a Parliamentary Democracy with Proportional Representation: A Valence-Uncertainty Model. British Journal of Political Science, 39, 539–558.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., & Merrill, S. (2013). Policy-Seeking Candidates Who Value the Valence Attributes of the Winner. Public Choice, 155, 139–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., Merrill, S., & Grofman, B. (2005). A Unified Theory of Party Competition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., Merrill, S., Simas, E., & Stone, W. (2011). When Candidates Value Good Character: A Spatial Model with Applications to Congressional Elections. Journal of Politics, 73(1), 17–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams, J., Scheiner, F. E., & Kawasumi, J. (2016). Running on Character? Running on Policy? An Analysis of Japanese Candidates’ Campaign Platforms. Electoral Studies, 44, 275–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, J. (1983). A Downsian Spatial Model with Party Activism. American Political Science Review, 77, 974–990.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez, R. M., Nagler, J., & Willette, J. R. (2000). Measuring the Relative Impact of Issues and the Economy in Democratic Elections. Electoral Studies, 19(2–3), 237–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere, S., & Iyengar, S. (1994). Does Attack Advertising Demobilize the Electorate? American Political Science Review, 88(4), 829–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere, S., & Snyder, J. M. (2000). Valence Politics and Equilibrium in Spatial Election Models. Public Choice, 103, 327–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aragones, E., & Palfrey, T. (2002). Mixed Equilibrium in a Downsian Model with a Favored Candidate. Journal of Economic Theory, 103, 131–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aragones, E., & Palfrey, T. (2004). The Effect of Candidate Quality on Electoral Equilibrium: An Experimental Study. American Political Science Review, 98(1), 77–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, S., & Bueno de Mesquita, E. (2009). Elections with Platform and Valence Competition. Games and Economic Behavior, 67(1), 191–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardi, L., & Ignazi, P. (1998). The Italian Party System: The Effective Magnitude of an Earthquake. In P. Ignazi & C. Ysmal (Eds.), The Organization of Political Parties in Southern Europe (pp. 91–109). Westport, CT: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, W. L., Blaney, J. R., & Pier, P. M. (2000). Acclaiming, Attacking and Defending: A Functional Analysis of US Nominating Convention Keynote Speeches. Political Communication, 17, 61–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A., Gidengil, E., Nadeau, R., & Nevitte, N. (2001). Measuring Party Identification: Britain, Canada and the United States. Political Behavior, 23(1), 5–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonanno, G. (1986). Vertical Differentiation with Cournot Competition. Economic Notes, 2, 68–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (1993). Rationalizing Parliamentary Systems. Discussion Paper Series in Economics and Econometrics, No. 9313, Economics Division, School of Social Sciences, University of Southampton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, D. J., & Geer, J. C. (2007). Beyond Negativity: The Effects of Incivility on the Electorate. American Journal of Political Science, 51(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Budge, I. (2001). Validating Party Policy Placements. British Journal of Political Science, 31, 210–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Budge, I., Klingemann, H. D., Volkens, A., Bara, J., & Tanenbaum, E. (Eds.). (2001). Mapping Policy Preferences. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Budge, I., & Laver, M. (Eds.). (1992). Party Policy and Government Coalitions. Basingstokes and London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bull, M., & Newell, J. L. (2005). Italian Politics: Adjustment Under Duress. London: Polity.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, E., & Hellwig, T. (2011). Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives Under Different Electoral Systems. American Journal of Political Science, 55(1), 27–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrubba, C. J., & Timpone, R. J. (2005). Explaining Vote Switching Across First- and Second-Order Elections. Evidence from Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 38(3), 260–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, J., & Patty, J. W. (2015). Valence and Campaigns. American Journal of Political Science, 59(4), 825–840.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E. C. (2005). Electoral Incentives for Political Corruption Under Open-List Proportional Representation. Journal of Politics, 67(3), 716–730.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chappell, H., & Keech, W. (1986). Policy Motivation and Party Differences in Dynamic Spatial Model of Party Competition. American Political Science Review, 80, 881–899.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, R. (1998). The Effect of Electoral Reforms on Campaign Practices in Japan: Putting New Wine into Old Bottles. Asian Survey, 38(10), 986–1004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, R. (2000). Ending the LDP Hegemony: Party Cooperation in Japan. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, H. D., Sanders, D., Steward, M. C., & Whiteley, P. (2004). Political Choice in Britain. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, H. D., Sanders, D., Steward, M. C., & Whiteley, P. (2010). Performance Politics and the British Voter. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. (1990). Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems. American Journal of Political Science, 34(4), 903. 935.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W. (1997). Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World’s Electoral Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L. (2011a). Negative Campaigning in No-Cabinet Alternation Systems. Japanese Journal of Political Science, 12(3), 399–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L. (2011b). Government Survival the Italian Way: The Ore and the Advantages of Policy Immobilism During the First Republic. European Journal of Political Research, 50, 110–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L. (2015a). An Italian Leitmotiv? Corruption and Competence in the Debates of the Italian Chamber of Deputies (1946–2014). South European Society and Politics, 20(4), 509–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L. (2015b). Explaining Party Ideological Stances. Public Choice, 162, 79–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L., & Hino, A. (2012). Missing Links in Party-System Polarization: How Institutions and Voters Matter. Journal of Politics, 74(2), 460–473.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L., Jou, W., & Memoli, V. (2015). Why Policy Representation Matters: The Consequences of Ideological Proximity Between Citizens and Their Governments. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L., & Martelli, P. (2009). I partiti della Prima Repubblica. Governi e maggioranze dalla Costituente a Tangentopoli. Rome: Carocci.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L., & Martelli, P. (2010). Ideological Proximity and Valence Competition. Negative Campaigning Through Allegation of Corruption in the Italian Legislative Arena from 1946 to 1994. Electoral Studies, 29(4), 636–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curini, L., & Martelli, P. (2015). A Case of Valence Competition in Elections: Parties’ Emphasis on Corruption in Electoral Manifestos. Party Politics, 21(5), 686–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curtis, G. (1971). Electoral Campaigning, Japanese Style. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont, C., Gabszewicz, J., & Thisse, J. (1979). On Hotelling’s Stability in Competition. Econometrica, 47, 1145–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Della Porta, D. (1992). Lo scambio occulto. Bologna: il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Della Porta, D., & Vannucci, A. (1997). The Resources of Corruption: Some Reflections from the Italian Case. Crime, Law and Social Change, 27, 231–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Della Porta, D., & Vannucci, A. (1999). Corrupt Exchanges. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Lonardo, L. (2016). Valence Uncertainty and the Nature of the Candidate Pool in Elections. Journal of Theoretical Politics. doi:10.1177/0951629816636486.

  • Dolezal, M., Ennser-Jedenastik, L., Muller, W. C., Praprotnik, K., & Winkler, A. K. (2016). Beyond Salience and Position Taking: How Political Parties Communicate Through Their Manifestos. Party Politics. doi:10.1177/1354068816678893.

  • Downs, A. (1957). An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duch, R. M., May, J., & Armstrong, D. (2010). Coalition-Directed Voting in Multi-Party Democracies. American Political Science Review, 104(4), 698–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elmelund-Præstekær, C. (2010). Beyond American Negativity: Toward a General Understanding of the Determinants of Negative Campaigning. European Political Science Review, 2, 137–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, J., & Hinich, M. (1982). Non Spatial Candidate Characteristics and Electoral Competition. Journal of Politics, 44, 115–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ensley, M. J. (2007). Candidate Divergence, Ideology, and Vote Choice in U.S. Senate Elections. American Politics Research, 35(1), 103–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esaiasson, P., & Narud, H. M. (2014). Between-Election Democracy: The Representative Relationship After Election Day. Colchester: ECPR Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farneti, P. (1980). The Italian Party System, 1945–1980. London: F. Pinter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L., & Grofman, B. (1991). Incumbency Advantage, Voter Loyalty and the Benefit of the Doubt. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 3(2), 115–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, S. L., Merrill, S., & Grofman, B. (2014). Modeling the Effects of Changing Issue Salience in Two-Party Competition. Public Choice, 158(3), 465–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. P., Abrams, S. A., & Pope, J. C. (2008). Polarization in the American Public: Misconceptions and Misreadings. Journal of Politics, 70, 556–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabel, M., & Huber, J. (2000). Putting Parties in Their Place. American Journal of Political Sciences, 44, 94–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galli, G. (1967). Il bipartitismo imperfetto. Bologna: il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galli, G. (1983). L’Italia sotterranea. Storia, politica, scandali. Roma-Bari: Laterza.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golden, M. (2007). Charges of Malfeasance, Preference Votes, Government Portfolios, and Characteristics of Legislators, Chamber of Deputies, Republic of Italy, Legislatures I–XI (1948–1994): Government Portfolios, hdl:1902.1/10196, Harvard Dataverse, V2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Golden, M., & Chang, E. C. (2001). Competitive Corruption: Factional Conflict and Political Malfeasance in Postwar Italian Christian Democracy. World Politics, 53(4), 588–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J. (2007). When Voters and Parties Agree: Valence Issues and Party Competition. Political Studies, 55(3), 629–655.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J., & Hobolt, S. B. (2008). Owning the Issue Agenda: Party Strategies and Vote Choices in British Elections. Electoral Studies, 27(3), 460–476.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J., & Jennings, W. (2012). Valence as Macro-Competence: An Analysis of Mood in Party Competence Evaluations in Great Britain. British Journal of Political Science, 42(2), 311–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grillo, M., & Polo, M. (1993). Political Exchange and the Allocation of Surplus: A Model of Two-Party Competition. In A. Breton, G. Galeotti, P. Salmon, & R. Wintrobe (Eds.), Preferences and Democracy (pp. 215–244). Dordrecht: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T. (2001). A Model of Candidate Location When One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage. American Journal of Political Science, 45(4), 862–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, K. R., & Summers, D. A. (1965). Cognitive Dependence on Linear and Nonlinear Cues. Psychological Review, 72, 215–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, K. M., & Pedersen, R. T. (2008). Negative Campaigning in a Multiparty System. Scandinavian Political Studies, 31(4), 408–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, J. E., & Hess, G. D. (1996). A Spatial Theory of Positive and Negative Campaigning. Games and Economic Behavior, 17, 209–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastie, R., & Dawes, R. M. (2010). Rational Choice in an Uncertain World: The Psychology of Judgment and Decision Making. Los Angeles: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herrera, H., Levine, D. K., & Martinelli, C. (2008). Platforms, Campaign Spending and Voter Participation. Journal of Public Economics, 92(3–4), 501–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling, H. (1929). Stability in Competition. Economic Journal, 39, 41–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ieraci, G. (2006). Governments, Policy Space and Party Positions in the Italian Parliament (1996–2001): An Inductive Approach to Parliamentary Debate and Votes of Investiture. South European Society and Politics, 11(2), 261–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inoguchi, T. (1987). Japan 1960–1980: Party Election Pledges. In I. Budge, D. Robertson, & D. Hearl (Eds.), Ideology, Strategy and Party Change: Spatial Analyses of Post-War Election Programmes in 19 Democracies (pp. 369–387). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Jessee, S. A. (2010). Partisan Bias, Political Information and Spatial Voting in the 2008 Presidential Election. Journal of Politics, 72, 327–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, C. (1986). Tanaka Kakuei, Structural Corruption, and the Advent of Machine Politics in Japan. Journal of Japanese Studies, 12, 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, H. M., & Fording, R. C. (1998). Voter Ideology in Western Democracies, 1946–1989. European Journal of Political Research, 33, 73–97.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klingemann, H. D., Volkens, A., Bara, J., & Budge, J. (Eds.). (2006). Mapping Policy Preference II. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohno, M. (1997). Japan’s Postwar Party Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohno, M. (2001). Why Didn’t the Japanese Socialists Moderate Their Politics Much Earlier to Become a Viable Alternative to the Liberal Democratic Party? In B. Grofman (Ed.), Political Science as Puzzle Solving. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kramer, J., & Rattinger, H. (1997). The Proximity and Directional Theories of Issue Voting: Comparative Results for the USA and Germany. European Journal of Political Research, 32(1), 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kroh, M. (2009). The Ease of Ideological Voting: Voter Sophistication and Party System Complexity. In H. D. Klingemann (Ed.), The Comparative Study of Electoral Systems (pp. 220–236). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunicova, J., & Rose-Ackerman, S. (2005). Electoral Rules and Constitutional Structures as Constraints on Corruption. British Journal of Political Science, 35, 573–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lachat, R. (2008). The Impact of Party Polarization on Ideological Voting. Electoral Studies, 27(4), 687–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, R., & Pomper, G. (2001). Negative Campaigning by US Senate Candidates. Party Politics, 7(1), 69–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lau, R., & Pomper, G. (2002). Effectiveness of Negative Campaigning in US Senate Elections. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 47–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. (2001). How Should We Estimate the Policy Positions of Political Actors? In M. Laver (Ed.), Estimating the Policy Position of Political Actors (pp. 239–245). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., & Benoit, K. (2003). The Evolution of Party Systems Between Elections. American Journal of Political Science, 47(2), 215–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., Benoit, K., & Garry, J. (2003). Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts Using Words as Data. American Political Science Review, 97(2), 311–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., & Schofield, N. (1990). Multiparty Governments: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., & Sergenti, E. (2012). Party Competition: An Agent-Based Model. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., & Shepsle, K. (1998). Events, Equilibria, and Government Survival. American Journal of Political Science, 42(1), 28–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lowe, W., Benoit, K., Mikhaylov, S., & Laver, M. (2011). Scaling Policy Preferences from Coded Political Texts. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 26(1), 123–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mastropaolo, A., & Slater, M. (1992). Party Policy and Coalition Bargaining in Italy, 1948–1987: Is There Order Behind the Chaos? In M. Laver & I. Budge (Eds.), Party Policy and Government Coalitions (pp. 312–345). Basingstoke: Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, D. R. (1974). Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazzoleni, G. (1991). Emergence of the Candidate and Political Marketing: Television and Election Campaigns in Italy in the 1980s. Political Communication, 8(3), 201–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarty, N., Poole, K., & Rosenthal, H. (2006). Polarized America: The Dance of Political Ideology and Unequal Riches. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, M., & Budge, I. (2005). Elections, Parties, and Democracy: Conferring the Median Mandate. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Meirowitz, A. (2008). Electoral Contests, Incumbency Advantages and Campaign Finance. Journal of Politics, 27, 681–699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mershon, C. (2001). Party Factions and Coalition Government: Portfolio Allocation in Italian Christian Democracy. Electoral Studies, 20, 555–580.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milanovic, B., Hoff, K., & Horowitz, S. (2008). Political Alternation as a Restraint on Investing in Influence. Policy Research Working Paper 4747, World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morlino, L. (1996). Crisis of Parties and Change of Party System in Italy. Party Politics, 2, 5–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morlino, L., & Tarchi, M. (1996). The Dissatisfied Society: The Roots of Political Change in Italy. European Journal of Political Research, 30, 41–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelken, D. (1996). The Judges and Political Corruption in Italy. Journal of Law and Society, 1, 95–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nyblade, B., & Reed, S. R. (2008). Who Cheats? Who Loots? Political Competition and Corruption in Japan, 1947–1993. American Journal of Political Science, 52(4), 926–941.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panebianco, A. (1988). Political Parties: Organization and Power. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Papke, L. E., & Wooldridge, J. M. (1996). Econometric Methods for Fractional Response Variables with an Application to 401(K) Plan Participation Rates. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11(6), 619–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papke, L. E., & Wooldridge, J. M. (2008). Panel Data Methods for Fractional Response Variables with an Application to Test Pass Rates. Journal of Econometrics, 145, 121–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plümper, T., & Martin, C. W. (2008). Multi-party Competition: A Computational Model with Abstention and Memory. Electoral Studies, 27, 424–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prescott, E., & Visscher, M. (1977). Sequential Location Among Firms with Foresight. The Bell Journal of Economics, 8, 378–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed, S. R. (1996). Political Corruption in Japan. International Social Science Journal, 149, 395–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rhodes, M. (1997). Financing Party Politics in Italy: A Case of Systemic Corruption. West European Politics, 20(1), 54–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richardson, B., & Flanagan, S. C. (1984). Politics in Japan. Boston: Little, Brown and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ridout, T. N., & Franz, M. (2008). Evaluating Measures of Campaign Tone. Political Communication, 25(2), 158–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. (1986). The Art of Political Manipulation. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sampson, A. (1977). The Arms Bazaar: From Lebanon to Lockheed. New York: Vicking Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. (1976). Parties and Party Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sberna, S., & Vannucci, A. (2013). It’s the Politics, Stupid! The Politicization of Anti-corruption in Italy. Crime, Law, and Social Change, 60, 565–593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scheiner, E. (2006). Democracy Without Competition in Japan: Opposition Failure in a One-Party Dominant State. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. (2003). Valence Competition in the Spatial Stochastic Model. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15(4), 371–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. (2004). Equilibrium in the Spatial Valence Model of Politics. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 16(4), 447–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N., & Sened, I. (2006). Multiparty Democracy: Parties, Elections and Legislative Politics in Multiparty Systems. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Serra, G. (2010). Polarization of What? A Model of Elections with Endogenous Valence. Journal of Politics, 72(2), 426–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shikano, S., & Käppner, K. (2014). Exploiting Feeling Thermometer Scores: A Simultaneous Estimation of Ideological Space and Valence Factors. Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, 3–6 April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sides, J. (2006). The Origins of Campaign Agendas. British Journal of Political Science, 36, 407–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sigelman, L., & Buell, E. H. (2004). Avoidance or Engagement? Issue Convergence in US Presidential Campaigns, 1960–2000. American Journal of Political Science, 48(4), 650–661.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, S. (2014). Linear and Quadratic Utility Loss Functions in Voting Behavior Research. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 26(1), 35–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S., & Grofman, B. (1995). Modelling Negative Campaigning. American Political Science Review, 89, 49–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stokes, D. E. (1963). Spatial Models of Party Competition. American Political Science Review, 57, 368–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka, A., & Martin, S. (2003). The New Independent Voter and the Evolving Japanese Party System. Asian Perspective, 27(3), 21–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teodori, M. (1999). Soldi ai partiti. Milano: Ponte alle Grazie.

    Google Scholar 

  • Verzichelli, L., & Cotta, M. (2000). Italy: From “Constrained” Coalitions to Alternative Governments? In W. C. Muller & K. Strøm (Eds.), Coalition Governments in Western Europe (pp. 433–497). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walter, A. S. (2014). Choosing the Enemy: Attack Behaviour in a Multiparty System. Party Politics, 20, 311–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wessels, B., & Schmitt, H. (2008). Meaningful Choices, Political Supply, and Institutional Effectiveness. Electoral Studies, 27, 19–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zakharov, A. V. (2009). A Model of Candidate Location with Endogenous Valence. Public Choice, 138, 347–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zakharova, M., & Warwick, P. (2014). The Sources of Valence Judgments: The Role of Policy Distance and the Structure of the Left-Right Spectrum. Comparative Political Studies, 47(14), 2000–2025.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luigi Curini .

Appendices

Appendix 1: Quadratic vs. Linear Utility Loss

Spatial models conceptualize individual utility over a particular alternative as maximized when the location of that alternative is identical to an individual’s ideological ideal point. Utility decreases as the distance between the alternative and the individual’s ideal point increases. That is, each individual’s preference curves are single-peaked and slope downward monotonically from the point of highest utility. While the idea that voters are more likely to support a party that largely shares their own preferences seems intuitive, and has served as a starting point for numerous studies on voting behaviour, scholars have devised different ways to capture how much weight citizen-party ideological proximity carries. Some researchers conceptualize the monotonic utility decrease as a linear function: for every increase of one unit in this distance, voters lose one unit’s worth of benefit, or utility (Blais et al. 2001; Krämer and Rattinger 1997; Wessels and Schmitt 2008). In this case, the utility i that derives from choosing party A can be represented as follows: U i = − |x i A|. Linear loss implies that as ideological distance increases, utility decreases at a uniform rate; a shift from a deviation of 0 units to 1 unit will affect the utility to the same extent as a shift from a deviation of 2 units to 3 units. In this sense, such function identifies actors that are risk-neutral (i.e. they face constant marginal losses). Other authors propose a quadratic relationship: for every increase of one unit in ideological distance, voters lose the square term of one unit’s worth of utility (Calvo and Hellwig 2011; Duch et al. 2010; Jessee 2010; Curini et al. 2015). This also means that such a quadratic loss ‘penalizes’ distant alternatives (those beyond 1 unit) at an increasing rate by squaring the deviations from one’s ideal point. To resume the previous example, the quadratic utility loss (used in Sect. 2.1 to derive Eq. (2.3)), would be for i: U i = − (x i A)2. For example, a shift from a deviation of 0 to a deviation of 1 unit will still register as a loss of ‘1’, while a shift from a deviation of 2–3 units will register as a loss of ‘5’ (32 − 22 = 5).

As already discussed in Sect. 2.1, the interpretation of a quadratic loss function is that actors are risk averse (i.e. they face increasing marginal losses), an assumption commonly made in the literature on spatial voting (Calvo and Hellwig 2011; Adams et al. 2005). Other authors, however, consider a linear loss function to be a better representation of human (and therefore voters’) behaviours (Hammond and Summers 1965; Hastie and Dawes 2010; Singh 2014).

Employing a linear loss function would imply some changes in the theoretical framework discussed in Sect. 2.1. In particular, Eq. (2.2) in Sect. 2.1 (i.e. the electors’ utilities to vote for L and R given a valence advantage for party L equal to k) would become:

$$ {u}_L(z)= k\hbox{--} a\left| x\hbox{--} z\right|,\kern0.875em {u}_R\left(\mathrm{z}\right)=\hbox{--} a\left| x+ d- z\right| $$
(2.4)

By equalizing u L (z) and u R (z) in Eq. (2.4), to find the location of the indifferent voter, three possible situations can be envisaged:

  1. (a)

    when \( d>\frac{k}{a} \), the increase in votes for L following a successful move in valence issues (i.e. producing k > 0 ) is \( \frac{k}{2 a} \), independently of the distance between party platforms;

  2. (b)

    when \( d>\frac{k}{a} \), party L takes all votes and party R obtains none;

  3. (c)

    similarly, when both parties share a similar platform, i.e. when d ≈ 0, any valence surplus of party L is sufficient to gain all votes.

Now, if it is admitted—as discussed earlier—that a valence campaign (i.e. the ability to produce k > 0) is costly, so that it is undertaken inasmuch as its expected benefits are huge, then the previous analysis at point (c) suggests that the opportunity to obtain a large(r) success in terms of votes through a successful valence campaign increases with the proximity between the platforms. Thus, exactly as happens with the quadratic loss function discussed in Sect. 2.1, one may conjecture that in a two-party system, a party envisages an inverse functional relation between the ideological distance from the rival and the incentive to engage in valence campaigning.

Note that point (c) above requires that the two parties share exactly the same position. This hypothesis can be relaxed by moving from a deterministic to a probabilistic voting model. In this latter case (see, for example, Chappell and Keech 1986), the general assumption is that the probability that parties ascribe to the vote of an elector with ideal point z depends on |x − z| − |a + d − z|, i.e. the difference of the distances between z and the parties’ locations on the left-right continuum. The closer this difference (i.e. the lower the value of d), the lower such probability becomes and vice-versa. Intuitively, this happens because the ability of voters to differentiate among parties’ locations in the policy space is also inversely related to d, given that the amount of (costly) information that voters would need to acquire to correctly differentiate parties’ locations when d is low increases substantially. But if that is true, then condition (c) above would hold also for values of d larger (although not substantially larger) than 0, given that in those situations for a voter the ‘perceived d’ would be almost 0. This should increase the incentives for a party to invest in a valence campaign, notwithstanding the fact that the ‘real d’ could be different (although not that much different) from 0.

Appendix 2: Policy vs. Valence Weight

Figure 2.4 in Sect. 2.1 illustrates party L’s incentive to campaign on valence as a function of the distance d between L and R. Note that, if I take the changing slope of party L’s incentive to play valence with respect to the distance between parties (i.e. ∂2 U L /∂kd = 1/2ad 2) as a measure of party L’s responsiveness to distance variation, then, by acknowledging that the hyperbola 1/2ad meets its axis of symmetry when the distance between parties is \( 1/\sqrt{2 a} \), I can derive that the critical distance where the hyperbola reaches its maximum curvature, and its slope is −1 as the ‘spatial divide’ between the zone where the incentive to campaign on valence issues is strong, although in a rapidly decreasing way, and the zone where that incentive begins to be more and more indifferent to valence competition and flatly decreases toward 0.

Moreover, because that critical distance depends inversely on a, it can be added to this conclusion that the higher the relative salience of the ideological competition with respect to L’s capacity to satisfy the electors’ preference for socially shared values, the smaller is the range of d where valence issues may play a significant electoral role. Conversely, the less parties’ electoral success is influenced by their ideological distance, the larger is the spatial range where valence campaigning will be rationally adopted. Figure 2.8, where two curves for two values of a ( > ) are plotted, illustrates the content of this paragraph.

Fig. 2.8
figure 8

Party L’s incentive to compete on valence depends on the variable d and on the parameter a

Note, however, that d and a are not independent from each other. According to the literature, the strength of policy or ideological voting (i.e. the value of a) increases with the degree of party system polarization (i.e. a measure that is inversely related to d; see Chap. 5) (Alvarez et al. 2000; Kroh 2009; Lachat 2008). With parties spread across the ideological spectrum, in fact, it may be easier for voters to identify differences among parties and thereby to select a party closer to their own views (Dalton 2010). This should increase the salience of policy as a function of party system polarization. 1 These arguments are coherent with the findings highlighted in several empirical papers (Ensley 2007; Green 2007; Green and Hobolt 2008), where it is shown that when candidates minimize their ideological distance, the salience of ideology (which in the model is measured by the a parameter) decreases in voters’ decisions and in candidates’ campaigning.

These findings are a good news for the present study. In fact, in the empirical analyses I never estimated a directly. Given what was noted just above, however, this can be somehow ‘safely’ neglected given that the value of a should change in the same direction of d.

Note

  1. 1.

    See Curini and Hino (2012) for a different perspective in this regard.

Appendix 3: Extracting Party Left-Right Scores from CMP Dataset

As discussed in Sect. 2.1, the CMP database takes 13 categories as indicators of policy positions representing the ‘left’ and another 13 as indicators of policy positions representing the ‘right’. The basis of the selection of such 26 categories is mainly theoretical: highly influential early modern theorists put them together in their political analyses. Left categories are linked in Marxist and progressive political analyses of around 1900, and contrast with right topics linked together in opposing analyses broadly supporting the existing order and market (Budge et al. 2001). Table 2.4 reports the list of these 26 categories together with the CMP denominations. 1

Table 2.4 The 26 CMP categories used to estimate a left and a right position

Moving from these 26 categories to a left-right score for a party has produced a wide debate in the literature. As discussed in Sect. 2.2, I have adopted the method originally proposed in Budge and Laver (1992), which still represents the benchmark when dealing with CMP data: in this case, the left-right position is constructed for each party in each election by subtracting the sum of its left statements from the sum of its right statements. In terms of raw numbers of quasi-sentences 2 coded into each category (rather than their percentage), it can be written as:

$$ \mathrm{Left}\ \mathrm{Right}\left(\mathrm{difference}\right)=\left( R- L\right)/\left( R+ L+ O\right)=\left( R- L\right)/ N, $$
(2.5)

where O refers to the ‘other 30 categories’ included in the CMP dataset but not in the 26 categories used to build a left-right position. This measure is therefore based on the difference in counts between left and right sentences normalized by the total number of sentences in the manifesto on any issue. Note that according to Eq. (2.5), counts of the categories not in the scale (i.e. O) still affect estimated party positions, so that it can happen that a party may be scored as less right-leaning (or left-leaning) by virtue of devoting more attention to topics that are not purely left or right (i.e. by increasing the value of O). The underlying assumption is that if an issue becomes less important, then a party will devote fewer sentences to it. This can be justified on the grounds that programmes are not just a compilation of discrete policy stands but integrated and complete statements all of whose constituent parts have been carefully considered in relation to each other by programme committees and party conventions and approved as a whole by the latter.

A first proposed alternative to Eq. (2.5) is to normalize the left-right scores estimated with the salience that each party assigns to the categories comprising the left-right scale as follows:

$$ \mathrm{Left}\ \mathrm{Right}\left(\mathrm{ratio}\right)=\left( R- L\right)/\left( R+ L\right) $$
(2.6)

The measure originally proposed by Kim and Fording (1998) ranges from −1 to 1 (rather than from −100 to 100 as in the Eq. (2.5) case) and makes the range constraint hidden in that measure explicit. Dividing by R + L decouples the measure from variation in the importance that a party assigns to any issue area (other than R and L). As a result, this measure will not necessarily create an apparent move to a more centrist position if the party decides to focus on other policy areas (given that O is not considered contrary to Eq. (2.5)). However, under some circumstances, Eq. (2.6) could force the left-right scores to the extremes, i.e. generating a score of −1 when R = 0 irrespective of the value of L, or to 1 when L = 0 irrespective of the value of R, leading to spikes at the boundaries of the scale.

A more recent alternative to Eq. (2.5) has been advanced by Lowe et al. (2011). In this case, the authors suggest focusing on the relative balance between quantity of sentences, or R/L. Note that by doing so, the marginal effect of one more quasi-sentence is decreasing in the amount that has already been said on the topic. For example, compare two situations: in the first one, the party’s previous platform contained 50 right-leaning sentences, and 20 left-leaning ones, then a new manifesto containing 50 right-leaning sentences and 21 left-leaning ones; in the second situation, the previous platform had contained 10 and 4 right and left-leaning sentences, and the new platform 10 and 5. The effect of adding one more sentence in the first case decreases the right-left ratio sentences by about 5% (50/20 = 2.5; 50/21 = 2.38; (2.38/2.5) − 1 = −5%), and in the second by 20% (10/4) = 2.5; 10/5 = 2; (2/2.5) − 1 = −20%). As a result, the left-right score of a party should be obtained by operating in proportions and working with a logarithmic scale relationship between the underlying quantity and subjective estimations of it. 3 That is:

$$ \mathrm{Left}\ \mathrm{Right}\left(\mathrm{logit}\right)= \log \left[\left( R+0.5\right)/\left( L+0.5\right)\right] $$
(2.7)

Despite their underlying differences, the three measures produce actually very similar results. 4 The correlation in the entire CMP dataset between Eqs. (2.5) and (2.6) is .957; between Eqs. (2.5) and (2.7) is .949.

Not surprisingly, therefore, if I replicate, for example, the analysis in the US case (see Sect. 2.2) by using the Eq. (2.6) or (2.7), the results are remarkably similar to the estimates that I obtain by using the Eq. (2.5) measure. See Table 2.5 in this respect.

Table 2.5 Explaining CORRUPTION in the US case according to SPATIAL PRESSURE (using alternative estimations of party left-right scores from CMP data)

Notes

  1. 1.

    See https://manifesto-project.wzb.eu/ for a detailed discussion of the meaning of each category.

  2. 2.

    A quasi-sentence is the coding unit employed in the CMP codification stage, i.e. the part of a text that contains exactly one statement. This also implies that in a given sentence, there may be more than one single quasi-sentence.

  3. 3.

    Using a logarithmic scale implies that exponentially more sentences in L or R are needed to move the policy position of a party toward an extreme position. The addition of 0.5 to Eq. (2.7) helps to make position estimates created from very small counts more stable.

  4. 4.

    An alternative approach to estimation of left-right scores for parties by employing CMP data is proposed by Gabel and Huber (2000). In their case, the left-right dimension is defined as the ‘super issue’ that most constrains parties’ positions across a broad range of policies. More in detail, they propose the use of factor analysis to extract the latent dimension that best accounts for the observed covariation across parties among all the categories in the dataset and treat it as the effective ideological dimension along which parties compete. See Curini and Martelli (2015) and Curini (2015a) for an application of this method in the case of valence campaigning with, respectively, CMP and legislative speeches data.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Curini, L. (2018). The Ideological Incentive for Campaigning on Corruption Issues: The Two-Party Case. In: Corruption, Ideology, and Populism. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-56735-8_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics