Skip to main content
Log in

In murky waters: a disentangling of corruption and related concepts

  • Published:
Crime, Law and Social Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Notes

  1. It should be noted that, following this comment, Lambsdorff [41] does launch into a very insightful discussion on the issue.

  2. For further discussion on this point see Kurer [40] or Scott [59].

  3. In both works, Machiavelli [45, 46] does mention actions which fit the contemporary notion of corruption as well. This underlines a point made below that corrumpere is a superset of corruption. Machiavelli’s work embeds a notion of currumpere as systemic [13]. That is, it is a problem at a societal rather than individual level. However, this is not a necessity for deviations from duty. More generally, neither corrumpere nor corruption or any of the other concepts discussed here are conceptually wedded to a particular level of analysis. Rather, from the perspective presented here Warren’s [65] critique that contemporary corruption is individualistic is only partially correct. While it is true that many analyses take the individual as a point of departure, this is not a logical extension of corruption as conceptualised below. For instance, corruption may be considered an informal institution [21] or indeed a systemic phenomenon [8].

  4. See Goertz’s Social Science Concepts [16] for a much more extensive discussion as well as some extensions of Sartori’s ideas.

  5. On a side note: Some might argue that particularistic governing is really a subset of corruption and not the other way around. I disagree on the following grounds: If corruption is indeed on a higher level of abstraction than nepotism, clientelism, pork barrel politics and patronage, the concept must encompass all these terms. What this would mean, however, is essentially an equation of corruption with particularistic governing, and the loss of an overarching conceptual category which demarcate the communalities between specific corrupt acts such as bribery and embezzlement. Such course of action implies an unnecessary loss of information, and–which is worse–conceptual stretching of the corruption concept.

  6. Instances where the legislative process is distorted by the corruption of parliamentary parties or their deputies [20, 65] are separate from this question and are fully in line with corruption as a special instance of particularistic government.

  7. There is no necessity in this lack of utility. The causes and consequences of corruption and pork barrel politics could well be similar. The point is we cannot know at a general level as the matter relates to which other concepts corruption and pork barrel politics are thought to be related to in a concrete study.

  8. Kopečký notes that patronage may be a necessary condition for corruption since the control of positions in the state is necessary for corrupt enrichment [34]. Certainly, bureaucrats need to ‘play along’ in order for most corrupt schemes involving political leadership to function [11, 35]. This, however, does not change the fact that the two phenomena are conceptually distinct, which is the main point I try to make here.

  9. Some authors use the term clientelism in a broader sense, encompassing what Kopečký [34] refers to as patronage (e.g. [31]). However, for the purpose of conceptual disentangling, which is the exercise performed here, a distinction between the two is fruitful.

  10. Clientelism as well might be argued to entail material rewards [59]. However, the rewards in this case befall the client outside politics and/or the bureaucracy, whereas corruption as defined for present purposes entails rewards for actors within these arenas. Clientelism, in this way, is corruption in reverse.

  11. Perhaps, I should explain: Consider a people of a certain country who engage frequently in deviations from the impartiality principle for material gain as they do not consider such an act to be corruption. This is not a conceptual issue; they are still engaging in corruption. What becomes interesting, of course, is why they do not consider what they are doing corrupt. Clearly, this is an explanatory question, which does not relate to the scholarly classification of their actions.

  12. Though, for instance, a political party’s gains from corrupt schemes may translate into electoral gain indirectly in a separate transaction.

  13. What constitutes the specific differences between a bribe and a gift is beyond the topic discussed here. A discussion can be found in Holmes [25]. Suffice it here to say that insofar as material inducements or rewards directed at public officials cause deviations from impartiality, they are to be regarded as corrupt.

References

  1. Adcock, R., & Collier, D. (2001). Measurement validity: A shared standard for qualitative and quantitative research. The American Political Science Review, 95(3), 529–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Anderson, J. H., & Gray, C. W. (2006). Anti-corruption in Transition 3, Who is Succeeding…and Why? Washington: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Andvig, J. C. (2006). Corruption and fast change. World Development, 34(2), 328–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Ashforth, B. E., Gioia, D. A., Robinson, S. L., & Treviño, L. K. (2008). Re-viewing organizational corruption. Academy of Management Review, 33(3), 670–684.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Bourgeois, L., III. (1981). On the measurement of organizational slack. Academy of Management Review, 6(1), 29–39.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Brooks, R. C. (1909). The nature of political corruption. Political Science Quarterly, 24(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Brown, A. J. (2006). What are we trying to measure? Reviewing the basics of corruption. In C. Sampford, A. Shacklock, C. Connors, & F. Galtung (Eds.), Measuring corruption (pp. 57–80). Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Caiden, G. E., & Caiden, N. J. (1977). Administrative corruption. Public Administration Review, 37(3), 301–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Collier, D., & Adcock, R. (1999). Democracy and dichotomies: A pragmatic approach to choices about concepts. Annual Review of Political Science, 2(1), 537–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Dahlström, C., Lapuente, V., & Teorell, J. (2012). The Merit of Meritocratization: Politics, Bureaucracy, and the Institutional Deterrents of Corruption. Political Research Quarterly, 65(3), 656–668.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Della Porta, D., & Vannucci, A. (1999). Corrupt exchanges: Actors, resources, and mechanisms of political corruption. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Dobel, J. P. (1978). The corruption of a state. The American Political Science Review, 72(3), 958–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Euben, J. P. (1978). On political corruption. The Antioch Review, 36(1), 103–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Fjeldstad, O. (2006). Corruption in tax administration: Lessons from institutional reforms in Uganda. In S. Rose-Ackerman (Ed.), International handbook on the economics of corruption (pp. 484–511). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Friedrich, C. (2001). Corruption Concepts in Historical Perspective. In A. Heidenheimer & M. Johnston (Eds.), Political corruption: Concepts and contexts (3rd ed., pp. 15–23). New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Goertz, G. (2006). Social science concepts: A user’s guide. New Jersey: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Golden, M. A. (2003). Electoral connections: the effects of the personal vote on political patronage, bureaucracy and legislation in postwar Italy. British Journal of Political Science, 33(2), 189–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Gray, C. W., Hellman, J. S., & Ryterman, R. (2004). Anticorruption in transition 2: Corruption in enterprise-state interactions in Europe and Central Asia, 1999–2002. Washington: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Heidenheimer, A. (1970). Introduction. In A. Heidenheimer (Ed.), Political corruption: Readings in comparative analysis (pp. 3–28). New York: Holt Rinehart and Winston.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Hellman, J. S., Jones, G., & Kaufmann, D. (2003). Seize the state, seize the day: state capture and influence in transition economies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 751–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Helmke, G., & Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal institutions and comparative politics: A research agenda. Perspectives on Politics, 2(4), 725–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Heywood, P. (1997). Political corruption: Problems and perspectives. Political studies, 45(3), 417–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Hicken, A. (2011). Clientelism. Annual Review of Political Science, 14, 289–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Holmberg, S., Rothstein, B., & Nasiritousi, N. (2009). Quality of government: What you get. Annual Review of Political Science, 12, 135–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Holmes, L. (2006). Rotten states? Corruption, post-communism, and neoliberalism. Durham: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Huntington, S. P. (1968). Political order in changing societies. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Jordan, W. C. (2009). Anti-corruption campaigns in thirteenth-century Europe. Journal of Medieval History, 35(2), 204–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M. (2009) Governance matters VIII: aggregate and individual governance indicators, 1996–2008. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4978

  29. Kitschelt, H. (2007). The demise of clientelism in affluent capitalist democracies. In H. Kitschelt & S. Wilkinson (Eds.), Patrons, clients, and policies: Patterns of democratic accountability and political competition (pp. 298–321). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  30. Kitschelt, H., Freeze, K., Kolev, K., & Wang, Y.-T. (2009). Measuring Democratic Accountability: An Initial Report on an Emerging Data Set. Revista de Ciencia Política, 29(3), 741–773.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Kitschelt, H., & Wilkinson, S. (2007). Citizen-politician linkages: an introduction. In H. Kitschelt & S. Wilkinson (Eds.), Patrons, clients, and policies: Patterns of democratic accountability and political competition (pp. 1–46). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  32. Klitgaard, R. (1988). Controlling corruption. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Knack, S. (2007). Measuring corruption: A critique of indicators in Eastern Europe and Central Asia. Journal of Public Policy, 27(3), 255–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Kopecký, P. (2011). Political competition and party patronage: Public appointments in Ghana and South Africa. Political Studies, 59(3), 713–732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Kopecký, P., Mair, P., & Spirova, M. (2012). Party Patronage as an Organizational Resource. In P. Kopeckỳ, P. Mair, & M. Spirova (Eds.), Party patronage and party government in European democracies (pp. 3–16). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  36. Kopecký, P., & Scherlis, G. (2008). Party patronage in Contemporary Europe. European Review, 16(3), 355–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Kopecký, P., & Spirova, M. (2011). “Jobs for the Boys”? Patterns of party patronage in post-communist Europe. West European Politics, 34(5), 897–921.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Kopecký, P., & Spirova, M. (2012). Measuring Patronage Through Structured Expert Interviews. In P. Kopeckỳ, P. Mair, & M. Spirova (Eds.), Party patronage and party government in European democracies (pp. 17–27). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  39. Kunicová, J., & Rose-Ackerman, S. (2005). Electoral rules and constitutional structures as constraints on corruption. British Journal of Political Science, 35(4), 573–606.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Kurer, O. (2005). Corruption: An alternative approach to its definition and measurement. Political Studies, 53(1), 222–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Lambsdorff, J. (2007). The institutional economics of corruption and reform: Theory, evidence, and policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  42. Lancaster, T. D., & Patterson, W. D. (1990). Comparative pork barrel politics. Comparative Political Studies, 22(4), 458–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. LaPalombara, J. (1994). Structural and institutional aspects of corruption. Social research, 61(2), 325–350.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Levitsky, S. (2007). From populism to clientelism? The transformation of labor-based party linkages in Latin America. In H. Kitschelt & S. Wilkinson (Eds.), Patrons, clients, and policies: Patterns of democratic accountability and political competition (pp. 206–226). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  45. Machiavelli, N. (1883). Discourses on the first decade of Titus Livius. London: Kegan Paul, Trench & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Machiavelli, N. (2010). The prince: The original classic. Chister: Capstone.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 681–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Miller, W. L., Grødeland, Å. B., & Koshechkina, T. Y. (2001). A culture of corruption? Coping with government in post-communist Europe. Budapest: Central European University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  49. O’Dwyer, C. (2006). Runaway state-building: Patronage politics and democratic development. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Offe, C. (2004). Political corruption. Conceptual and practical issues. In J. Kornai & S. Rose-Ackerman (Eds.), Building a trustworthy state in post-socialist transition (pp. 77–99). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Philp, M. (2006). Corruption definition and measurement. In C. Sampford, A. Shacklock, C. Connors, & F. Galtung (Eds.), Measuring corruption (pp. 45–56). Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1975). The economics of corruption. Journal of Public Economics, 4(2), 187–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Rose-Ackerman, S. (1999). Corruption and government: Causes, consequences, and reform. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  54. Rothstein, B. (2011). The quality of government: Corruption, social trust, and inequality in international perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  55. Rothstein, B., & Teorell, J. (2008). What is quality of government? A theory of impartial government institutions. Governance, 21(2), 165–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  56. Sartori, G. (1970). Concept Misformation in comparative politics. The American Political Science Review, 64(4), 1033–1053.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  57. Sartori, G. (1991). Comparing and Miscomparing. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 3(3), 243–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  58. Scott, J. C. (1969). Corruption, machine politics, and political change. The American Political Science Review, 63(4), 1142–1158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  59. Scott, J. C. (1972). Comparative political corruption. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Seligson, M. A. (2002). The impact of corruption on regime legitimacy: A comparative study of four Latin American countries. Journal of Politics, 64(2), 408–433.

    Google Scholar 

  61. Stern, H. J. (1971). Prosecutions of local political corruption under the Hobbs act: The unnecessary distinction between bribery and extortion. Seton Hall Law Review, 3(1), 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  62. Thomas, M. A. (2010). What Do the Worldwide Governance Indicators Measure? European Journal of Development Research, 22(1), 31–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  63. Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76(3), 399–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  64. Waltzer, M. (1983). Spheres of justice: A defense of pluralism and equality. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  65. Warren, M. E. (2004). What does corruption mean in a democracy? American Journal of Political Science, 48(2), 328–343.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kim Sass Mikkelsen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mikkelsen, K.S. In murky waters: a disentangling of corruption and related concepts. Crime Law Soc Change 60, 357–374 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-013-9474-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-013-9474-6

Keywords

Navigation