Skip to main content

Interparty Competition in the Governmental Arena

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Deinstitutionalization of Western European Party Systems

Abstract

This chapter shifts the focus to governments. Starting from Mair’s concepts of closure and openness, we analyze trends and variations in governmental properties such as alternation, innovation, and formula. We find that the governmental arena seems to tell a somewhat different story compared to the electoral and parliamentary ones. Here, a certain degree of fluidity had always existed, even in times when the interparty competition for votes and parliamentary seats was frozen. However, a clear deinstitutionalization process is not detectable, not even in the last decade, although some signs of increasing openness are emerging. It seems that the change emerged in the 2010s in the electoral arena has yet to reach Rokkan’s threshold of ‘executive power’.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In Anglo-Saxon countries and especially in the United Kingdom, cabinet refers to the executive body, while government refers broadly to executive power and activity, also including the parliamentary majority. In the rest of Western Europe, the two terms tend to overlap and are used synonymously, which is also the choice of this work.

  2. 2.

    As a result, a total of 632 cabinets have been taken into account.

  3. 3.

    Similarly, Casal Bértoa and Enyedi (2016, 266) argue that ‘the seizure of governmental power is the principal, even if not the only, prize of party competition’.

  4. 4.

    With the exception of his 2007 work, where he also proposed a fourth indicator, as discussed in the previous section.

  5. 5.

    Familiar formulas design the governing formulas among the parties within the ‘cartel’ (Kats & Mair, 1995).

  6. 6.

    Unlike Casal Bértoa and Enyedi (2016), we based our calculation on ministerial positions (seats) instead of ministers because our emphasis is on governmental positions, not persons. In this way, if a politician holds two ministries in the same cabinet, it contributes twice to the share of seats of his/her own party. Notice that only the minister positions have been considered, while the deputy minister and undersecretary positions have been excluded. The methodological choices concerning the rules for calculating volatility (e.g., splits and mergers) are exactly the same as those used in Chapter 3. The share of seats held by independent ministers has been included in the calculation of volatility be comparing it across time as it was an individual party, regardless of the identity of the technical ministers.

  7. 7.

    GAlt = (50 − |TGV − 50|)*2 where TGV = \(\frac{{\sum_{i = 1}^n | p_{it -} p_{i\left( {t + 1} \right)|} }}{2}\) where n is the number of parties and pi represents the percentage of ministerial seats obtained by that party in time periods t and t + 1.

  8. 8.

    GInn = \(\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^n p_{i\left( {t + 1} \right)}\) where n is the number of parties and pi represents the percentage of ministerial seats gained by that party at t + 1. The same rules followed in Chapters 3 and 4 for calculating new parties apply also here (see also Emanuele, 2016; Emanuele & Chiaramonte, 2019).

  9. 9.

    Like the formation of the coalition between the social-democrats (SDP) and the liberal-democrats (FDP) in Germany in 1969. Both parties had governed before, but they had never done this together. Moreover, note that the first fully technocratic government (i.e., a cabinet made exclusively by independent ministers, without the presence of any political party)—if any—in a given country has been considered an innovative formula. The calculation of Formula starts from the first government of the second legislature, thus taking all cabinets in office in the first legislature as a reference for familiarity.

  10. 10.

    Note that GAlt and Formula have 375 observations instead of 376 (like TV and TPV, see Chapter 3) as democratic governments in Portugal starts in 1976 and therefore the first legislature considered here is that starting in 1979. Conversely, for TV and TPV we also have the 1976 data point as it is comparable with the 1975 Constituent Assembly election. Consistently with EInn and PInn, GInn has only 356 observations as its calculation starts from the third legislature of each country, thus taking the first two legislatures as reference (see also Morlino, 1998).

  11. 11.

    On average, in the 20 countries under study, 1.73 cabinets have taken place for each legislature.

  12. 12.

    In our dataset, the Cronbach’s alpha is 0.47, while Pearson’s r correlation is 0.01 between GAlt and GInn, 0.27 between GAlt and Formula, and 0.56 between GInn and Formula. A principal component analysis shows that only the first component has an eigenvalue above 1, which means that the three measures are structured around one principal component.

  13. 13.

    Moreover, these six legislatures account for 35.6% of the total amount of GInn in the data.

  14. 14.

    In the panel-corrected standard error regression with country fixed effect, Formula is significant at p < 0.1 if we consider the full dataset (N  = 375) but it increases to p < 0.01 if we simply exclude the first legislature for which we have information in each country (N = 356).

  15. 15.

    In Greece and the United Kingdom substantial access to new parties (GInn is, respectively, 7.11 and 6.45 on average) seems to lower the predictability of the party system. However, by going into detail, we notice that the high GInn is mostly due to a single legislature (1981–1985 in Greece and 1951–1955 in the United Kingdom), characterized by the first alternation in government of, respectively, the PASOK and the Conservative Party (GInn = 100). With these important exceptions, access to new parties is a rare event in both countries. Specifically, in Greece, ‘with the minor and short-lived exception of the so-called “ecumenical” coalitions (between July 1989 and February 1990 as well as November 2011 and February 2012), between 1974 and 2011 governmental changes were always wholesale (i.e. complete or no change in government composition), extremely familiar governmental formulae (either the conservative ND, or the socialist PASOK), and the number of parties with a chance of forming a government limited exclusively to these two’ (Casal Bértoa, 2019, 571–573).

  16. 16.

    Italy’s GInn since 1994 is even higher than Spain’s, even though Spain appears in Table 5.1 as the country showing, on average, the highest governmental innovation in Western Europe (GInn = 14.92). However, in Spain, the access of new parties to government has only occurred three times, all signaling relevant events in the country’s history: the first alternation in government of PSOE (1982), PP (1996), and the entry of Podemos into the center-left coalition with the PSOE after the November 2019 election.

  17. 17.

    We should note that we are considering legislatures, not single cabinets, so all types can take place in principle. Indeed, while in a single cabinet we cannot have a familiar formula and the presence of new parties, in a legislature with multiple cabinets we can have a weighted average Formula below the mean (and hence ‘familiar’) due to the presence of more familiar than innovative cabinets in the legislature, and GInn above the mean (with the entry of new parties in other cabinets of the same legislatures).

  18. 18.

    The full temporal trend of each country for all three measures is reported in the Appendix (Figs. 5.7, 5.8, and 5.9).

References

  • Bartolini, S., & Mair, P. (1990). Identity, competition, and electoral availability: The stabilisation of European electorates 1885–1985. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browne, E. C., Frendreis, J. P., & Gleiber, D. W. (1984). An “events” approach to the problem of cabinet stability. Comparative Political Studies, 17(2), 167–197.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casal Bértoa, F. (2014). Party systems and cleavage structures revisited: A sociological explanation of party system institutionalization in East Central Europe. Party Politics, 20(1), 16–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casal Bértoa, F. (2017). Political parties or party systems? Assessing the ‘myth’ of institutionalisation and democracy. West European Politics, 40, 402–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casal Bértoa, F. (2018). The three waves of party system institutionalisation studies: A multi-or uni-dimensional concept?. Political Studies Review, 16(1), 60–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casal Bértoa, F. (2019). The calm before the storm: Explaining the institutionalization of Southern European party systems before the great recession. European Politics and Society, 20(5), 567–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casal Bértoa, F., & Enyedi, Z. (2016). Party system closure and openness: Conceptualization, operationalization and validation. Party Politics, 22, 265–277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casal Bértoa, F., & Mair, P. (2012). Party system institutionalization across time in post-communist Europe. In F. Müller-Rommel & H. Keman (Eds.), Party government in the new Europe (pp. 85–112). Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casal Bértoa, F., & Weber, T. (2019). Restrained change: Party systems in times of economic crisis. The Journal of Politics, 81(1), 233–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duverger, M. (1954). Political parties: Their organization and activity in the modern state. Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Emanuele, V. (2016). Dataset of new parties and party system innovation in Western Europe since 1945. Italian Center for Electoral Studies. Retrieved November 15, 2020, from https://doi.org/10.7802/1363

  • Emanuele, V., & Chiaramonte, A. (2019). Explaining the impact of new parties in the Western European party systems. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties, 29(4), 490–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emanuele, V., & Sikk, A. (2021). Party crashers? Modeling genuinely new party development paths in Western Europe. Party Politics, 27(5), 883–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enyedi, Z., & Casal Bértoa, F. (2018). Institutionalization and de-institutionalization in post-communist party systems. East European Politics and Societies: and Cultures, 32(3), 422–450. https://doi.org/10.1177/0888325417736808

  • Franklin, M., Mackie, T., & Valen, H. (Eds.). (1992). Electoral change: Responses to evolving social and attitudinal structures in western countries. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, R. S., & Mair, P. (1995). Changing models of party organization and party democracy: The emergence of the cartel party. Party Politics, 1(1), 5–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krauss, S. (2018). Stability through control? The influence of coalition agreements on the stability of coalition cabinets. West European Politics, 41(6), 1282–1304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane, J.-E., & Ersson, S. (2007). Party system instability in Europe: Persistent differences in volatility between west and east? Democratization, 14, 92–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. (2003). Government termination. Annual Review of Political Science, 6(1), 23–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy: Government forms and performance in thirty-six democracies. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipset, S. M., & Rokkan, S. (1967). Cleavage structures, party systems and voter alignments: An introduction. In S. M. Lipset & S. Rokkan (Eds.), Party systems and voter alignments: Cross-national perspectives (pp. 1–64). The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lupia, A., & Strøm, K. (1995). Coalition termination and the strategic timing of parliamentary elections. American Political Science Review, 89(3), 648–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, S., & Scully, T. R. (1995). Building democratic institutions: Party systems in Latin America. Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mair, P. (1996). Party systems and structures of competition. In L. LeDuc, R. G. Niemi, & P. Norris (Eds.), Comparing democracies: Elections and voting in global perspectives (pp. 83–106). Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mair, P. (1997). Party system change: Approaches and interpretations. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mair, P. (2007). Party systems and alternation in government, 1950–2000: Innovation and institutionalization. In S. Gloppen & L. Rakner (Eds.), Globalisation and democratisation: Challenges for political parties (pp. 135–53). Fagbokforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morlino, L. (1998). Democracy between consolidation and crisis: Parties, groups, and citizens in Southern Europe. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Müller, W. C., & Strom, K. (Eds.). (2000). Coalition governments in western Europe. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Müller-Rommel, F. (2005). Party competition in central and eastern European democracies: On the connection between the structures of government formation and the stability of party systems. Journal of Parliamentary Issues, 36(3), 666–679.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pedersen, M. N. (1979). The dynamics of European party systems: Changing patterns of electoral volatility. European Journal of Political Research, 7(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pilet, J. B. (2021). Hard times for governing parties: The 2019 federal elections in Belgium. West European Politics, 44(2), 439–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rokkan, S. (1970). Citizens: Elections, parties. Universitetsforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, R., & Urwin, D. W. (1970). Persistence and change in western party systems since 1945. Political Studies, 18(3), 287–319. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9248.1970.tb00436.x

  • Siaroff, A. (2000). Comparative European party systems: An analysis of parliamentary elections since 1945. Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. (1976). Parties and party systems: A framework for analysis. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, G. (1989). Core persistence: Change and the ‘people’s party.’ West European Politics, 12(4), 157–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R., & Sikk, A. (2010). Parsimonious model for predicting mean cabinet duration on the basis of electoral system. Party Politics, 16(2), 261–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tukey, J. W. (1949). Comparing individual means in the analysis of variance. Biometrics, 5(2), 99–114. University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alessandro Chiaramonte .

Appendix

Appendix

See Figs. 5.6, 5.7, 5.8, and 5.9.

Fig. 5.6
figure 6

Evolution of GAlt, Ginn, and Formula over time in Western Europe, linear and quadratic fit

Fig. 5.7
figure 7

Trend of GAlt by country, Western Europe (1946–2019)

Fig. 5.8
figure 8

Trend of GInn by country, Western Europe (1946–2019)

Fig. 5.9
figure 9

Trend of Formula by country, Western Europe (1946–2019)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Chiaramonte, A., Emanuele, V. (2022). Interparty Competition in the Governmental Arena. In: The Deinstitutionalization of Western European Party Systems. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-97978-2_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics