Introduction

Recent years have seen a strong and sustained call for greater government transparency; international organizations and NGOs advocate transparency as a necessary condition for better government quality, greater accountability, thus limiting the scope for corruption with impunity (see i.e. [1,2,3,4,5,6]). The theoretical arguments behind the instrumental value of transparency are by now well established and are found in such varying fields as negotiation theory [7], public management [8, 9], and regime effectiveness [10]. While empirical investigations exist, we argue that the findings leave important questions unresolved due to the breadth of the measures used. Existing definitions provide a useful baseline but greater precision, disaggregation and delineation are needed to allow for more stringent empirical investigation [8, 11]. Transparency is at times conflated with “good governance”, and measures tend to tap into closely related phenomena such as accountability, participation and the capacity of government institutions more generally, making it difficult to discern whether observed associations speak to the importance of transparency specifically.

The value of transparency lies in its purported influence on government probity and effectiveness as well as on the functioning of markets. In terms of government performance, and more specifically the prevalence of corruption, the logic is undeniably compelling: since information asymmetries are a primary obstacle to principals’ ability to hold agents accountable, lowering the information barrier ought to enable scrutiny and monitoring, without which it is impossible to detect and sanction abuses of public power. Such claims have until recently mostly been the subject of empirical scrutiny in single country and experimental studies, as cross country data on transparency have been wanting (e.g. [12,12,14]). The research community has fortunately begun to address this gap [15,15,17, 70]. While a welcome development, we argue that the breadth of the cross-country measures used in these studies risks introducing unhelpful tautologies in empirical investigations of the effects of transparency on other aspects of government.

This paper advances an argument for more delimited operationalizations of transparency that are sensitive to two situational characteristics: the intended principals as well as the expected use of the information, i.e. the purpose. The paper introduces a new measure of government transparency designed to capture these parameters with respect to transparency intended to allow for the detection and exposure of government corruption. A primary aim of the paper is therefore to advocate for greater conceptual and operational precision in studies of transparency in order to disaggregate it from the overall level of political development and capacity of the state. Without such precision, it is impossible to produce reliable analyses of the effects of transparency on the prevalence of corruption.

The paper is structured as follows. Section one discusses the conceptualizations of transparency and existing claims regarding its beneficial implications, and argues that existing definitions, while useful for some research questions, are too broad and all-encompassing to allow for explorations of the specific link between transparency and government corruption. Section two discusses the strengths and weaknesses of existing approaches to the measurement of government transparency. We then introduce a novel measure of transparency from the Quality of Government survey of public administration experts, and examine the measure in terms of convergent and divergent validity compared to existing measures of transparency. The analyses then show that the measure introduced here correlates with existing measures of corruption, and that -in contrast to existing measures- the correlation is independent of measures of state capacity and political development more generally.

What is government transparency?

The arguments linking openness and information to accountability, to democracy and to government honesty and effectiveness are highly compelling theoretically, yet rest on many assumptions about how institutions and actors act and interact, assumptions which have only recently become subject to empirical scrutiny [18]. Work to conceptualize transparency has lamentably not developed in step with these trends, which means that conceptualizations and operationalization of transparency have tended to remain at higher levels in the ladder of abstraction ( [19,19,21], 1040). The measures that have recently emerged, discussed in greater detail below, may hence be useful in exploring the causes and consequences of political development and government openness in the broadest sense, but are less useful – and may potentially even yield misleading results – when used to examine more fine-grained theoretical claims. In order to unpack this argument, we first introduce a more nuanced framework for conceptualizing transparency and then present arguments for why existing definitions, and subsequently attempts at measurement, are useful for addressing some empirical questions but not others.

Transparency is, without a doubt, a multifaceted concept but at times has been made unhelpfully broad to the point that it has been conflated with participation, accountability, state capacity or even corruption, impartiality, and rule of law. Christopher Hood traces the history of the concept and identifies the “broadest doctrine of openness” as "...the doctrine that the general conduct of executive government should be predictable and operate according to published (and as far as possible non-discretionary) rules rather than arbitrarily" ( [22], 14). Hood’s analysis illustrates transparency has tended to bleed conceptually into other normative standards of good government. The World Trade Organization states, in an illustrative case in point, that ensuring “transparency” in international commercial treaties typically involves three core requirements: (i) to make information on relevant laws, regulations and other policies publicly available, (ii) to notify interested parties of relevant laws and regulations and changes to them; and (iii) to ensure that laws and regulations are administered in a uniform, impartial and reasonable manner [23]. This definition includes not only making information available and accessible to stakeholders, but also that laws and regulations be administered and implemented in an impartial and predictable manner, a core element of rule of law yet outside the scope of the concept of government transparency.Footnote 1

Many authors take variations of Florini’s definition – “the release of information which is relevant for evaluating institutions” [8] – as a point of departure for conceptualizing transparency. Subsequent work has to some extent narrowed in on two components of transparency: visibility and inferability [24]. As expressed in Gregory Michener’s recent review of efforts to capture transparency empirically: “The essential idea is that “transparent” information should be visible in the sense of being complete and easily accessible and inferable in the sense of lending itself to accurate conclusions” ( [25], 185; [24], 234). The stipulations of availability and accuracy are normatively compelling, perhaps even incontrovertible, yet still leave the definition quite vast. In Michener’s later piece [25], in which he reviews and critically evaluates international transparency policy indexes (ITPIS) often used in the policy community, he instead advances a case for methodological pluralism and a need to examine the considerable variation among the various institutions in a single polity, a call with which we agree and which necessitates a more refined theoretical apparatus.

Taking this line of argumentation a step further, we advocate that the empirical study of transparency requires greater conceptual precision and, more importantly, operationalizations tailored to the situational specifics, in particular paying attention to the purpose for which information is to be used, as well as the intended users, i.e. the principals (government offices, voters, and non-state actors acting outside of electoral institutions). The purpose and principals require different types of information, with more involved principals generally needing more detailed and comprehensive information. What different purposes might transparency thus serve? The purposes of government transparency may be of three ilks: deliberation, predictability, and accountability. Starting with deliberation, i.e. column D Table 1, transparency in policy making allows, according to some normative theorists, for more extensive and meaningful participation in policy-making [26]. The availability of information in the input stage of the political process does not axiomatically lead to participation and deliberation (and too much openness may even impede deliberation under some circumstances, see [27, 28]), but the disclosure of information to stakeholders in policy making is indisputably a precondition of successful deliberation.

Table 1 The purpose and principals of transparency: typology of information

In terms of predictability (column C Table 1), information regarding rules and regulations, as well as the implications for failure to comply with rules and regulations, have been pointed to as necessary preconditions of a stable investment climate, lowering risks in market transactions [5]. As with deliberation, this is not to say that fair and impartial implementation and enforcement of rules, i.e. rule of law, becomes folded into the definition of transparency, as rules may be equally well published in two settings but to varying degrees enforced consistently and impartially (c.f. [22], 14). In order to adequately test the merits of transparency empirically for investment behavior, it would thus be essential that the concept not stretch to include impartial enforcement of rules.

The third overarching purpose of transparency – and the one that brings us to the link to anti-corruption efforts – is accountability (columns A and B Table 1). Analogous to both deliberation and predictability, theoretical arguments that transparency constitutes a necessary precondition to accountability are highly compelling, yet here as well, the concept should not be stretched to include accountability in its entirety by including elements of sanctioning, or even the capacity and performance of agents (government agencies) more generally [20, 29]. Accountability implies a number of components: 1) that an agent provides – routinely or upon demand – an account to principals regarding activities related to a specific domain, 2) that the agent justify/explain decisions and 3) that the principal has the authority and the means to sanction the agent effectively ( [20], 209). Transparency thus only refers to the first of these components. When measures of transparency incorporate additional components of accountability, empirical investigations may suggest that transparency is strongly associated with less corruption. Yet in the policy world, transparency measures refer only to access to information, and do not require answerability or sanctioning. Developing measures that better correspond to transparency as defined in policy circles is therefore necessary to understand whether, and under what conditions, government transparency leads to lower levels of corruption.

Transparency in various forms is hypothesized to enable several different forms of accountability, including horizontal (intra-governmental), vertical (electoral), and diagonal (societal).Footnote 2 Each of these forms of accountability implies a distinct category of principals, but also may have two more specific, albeit interrelated, accountability functions (column A versus B Table 1). The first relates to policy performance, for which information regarding outcomes is the most relevant, and the other relating to the legal and ethical use of public power. Accountability for policy performance (column B) – which may be horizontal as when legislative assemblies take corrective action with respect to policy performance, but may also be vertical, as when the electorate votes retrospectively based on performance. Both require information on social and economic conditions detailed enough to track change.

Accountability exercised to ensure probity and honest stewardship of public resources (column B), our main focus and the type of transparency captured by the measures introduced below, requires information regarding, in particular, government finances, i.e. revenues, transfers and expenditures. Some of the more common and deleterious forms of corruption involve diverting or embezzling funds as well as requiring irregular payments for contracts or licenses, and the ability to track fiscal flows both into and out of public coffers is therefore a necessary precondition to detect such activity. In addition, mechanisms such as whistleblower protections further strengthen transparency with the purpose of exposing malfeasance and corruption in its various forms.

The second situational parameter which the operationalization of transparency ought to take into account, is, we argue, the intended principal(s). Several authors regard principals as an integral part of the definition of transparency, as in Kaufmann’s [30] definition of transparency as the “increased flow of timely and reliable economic, social and political information, which is accessible to all relevant stakeholders” (see also [31]). Yet without stipulating the intended stakeholders, or principals, operationalizations of transparency may fail to take into account that information may be accessible to, for example, initiated experts but impenetrable to a lay audience. Moreover, bringing to light the issue of the intended principal uncovers another relevant parameter in the conceptualization of transparency as it relates to government corruption, namely the matter of who controls the flow of information and whether principals may request information, and not merely partake of the information that agents elect to publish. A government agency may for example publish information only very selectively, such as simple pie charts indicating revenues and expenditures, but also willingly open its books to formal auditors and the lay public alike upon request, while another may publish more information a priori but deny (by intent or omission) requests for additional documentation [17]. Measures that ignore this distinction risk overestimating the availability of useful information, as they reflect the volume of information and ignore actual utility for the intended purpose of information; agents may strategically abstain from publicizing information that may reveal malfeasance and culpability.

In terms of transparency as it relates to constraining corruption, principals may include government offices – e.g. offices of internal oversight, elected assemblies, the judiciary – as well as non-state actors, i.e. citizens, civil society associations, and the media. In polities in which corruption is endemic, many government actors and institutions may be enmeshed in, and therefore gain from, the same self-serving behavior and disregard of rules which they are tasked with detecting and sanctioning in others. Where pervasive, in other words, corruption in all likelihood undermines government actors’ incentives to hold one another accountable regardless of the availability of information, what Timothy Besley has termed the problem of the lack of a principled principal ( [32]; see also [33]). Many in the policy community have therefore pointed to non-state actors as the most plausible honest principals, as they have greater incentives to redress abuses. Although these claims rest on a number of strong assumptions about political reality [1, 18], the measure proposed here nonetheless seeks to capture the extent to which the public has access to information relevant to detecting venality.

The next section reviews some recent attempts to measure transparency and argues that many of them cast a wide net, tending to capture government transparency but also other attributes of government quality. If transparency is not measured distinctly from related concepts such as accountability, participation or state capacity, resulting measures are of limited use in investigating how transparency relates empirically to these other normative goods.

Approaches to measurement

Disentangling transparency from empirically and conceptually related phenomena, such as state capacity, accountability and participation is analytically feasible and necessary to understand the policy mechanisms and dynamics by which political systems reach and maintain higher levels of political development. While the distinction between transparency and accountability are discussed above, we now turn to distinguishing government transparency from state capacity. Collecting, compiling, computing and publishing reliable information in a timely manner requires a certain type and level of institutional capacity (along with political will), but state capacity extends far beyond this type and level. State capacity in its broadest sense extends well beyond the resources and competencies required to collect and organize information to include the entirety of government institutions involved in the collection of taxes, enforcement of laws, the protection of private property, and the provision of public goods and services, among other things (e.g. [34, 35]). Soifer [36], for example, delineates three dimensions of state capacity – coercive, fiscal and administrative – and a government’s ability to compile and publish relevant information would only rely on administrative capacity, and not even that dimension in its entirety. Capacity to track and report on societal conditions may well correlate with other aspects of state capacity, it does not necessarily always do so. Institutional capacity has been shown to vary considerably among state organizations, and it is therefore crucial to develop targeted measures of transparency that do not tap extensively into the aspects of state capacity not related to compiling and publishing information. Insum, measures that tap extensively into a state’s capacity in a broad sense, or incorporate measures relating to accountability mechanisms or even citizens’ confidence in government bodies, cannot be used to study the significance of transparency for other specific aspects of government performance without introducing risk of false positives, or type I errors [25].

Although long overlooked in cross country empirical research, and in particular when compared to the groundswell of research efforts devoted to understanding and measuring corruption, recent years have seen several important and helpful attempts to capture the concept of transparency empirically. Studies of the effects of transparency have employed several approaches to measurement: composite indices comprising a broad spectrum of indicators, where some extend conceptually beyond transparency [23, 70]; specific indicators of transparency such as expert assessments of legal frameworks, or surveys of governments’ publication of relevant information and statistics or proxy measurements, such as press freedom [37] or newspaper circulation [15, 38]. While media freedom is a requisite condition for the circulation of information relevant to scrutinizing government, measures of media freedom do not relate directly to government and its operations, and therefore tap into contextual factors outside the realm of the state. These will therefore not be discussed further here. Composite indices are, however, currently the best available option for measuring government transparency, and a more detailed discussion of their strengths and weaknesses is therefore warranted.

Composite indices of transparency build on the basis of a wide range of data sources and, using a similar logic to the widely used indices of corruption and governance such as the World Bank’s Governance Indicators or Transparency International’s Corruption Perception Index, include indicators that use a plurality of definitions of transparency and data collection strategies. Williams [70] brings together data from 29 sources and derives annual scores for 1980 through 2010 for 190 countries. Similarly, although available for one year only, Bellver and Kaufmann [23] build transparency indices on 13 surveys carried out in 2003 and 2004 by various international organizations and nonprofit organizations.

Finally, broad composite indicators risk missing the important distinctions among trees in efforts to depict the entire forest. As Michener ([25], 184), indices are generally not guided by policy theories regarding which aspects of the phenomenon being measured are crucial versus which may simply improve government in a general normative sense. He writes: “indexes presuppose substitutability while policies contain non-substitutable ‘necessary’ policy provisions”, suggesting that “policies can rank favorably on indexes notwithstanding the absence of lynchpin policy provisions.” Scheppele [39] makes a similar point with respect to rule of law indicators, which may rate states on component parts, even if those components add up to a Frankenstate which does not at all embody and assure rule of law. Aggregate scores may therefore reflect how well a state ticks a number of boxes considered favorable without regard to which features are crucial and which are less essential. In other words, broad indices may capture more than government transparency itself, but in doing so may blur and thus fail to capture the actual variation relevant to exploring the empirical questions at hand.Footnote 3 These points suggest a need for measures to be attentive to the de facto condition under study, and not merely aggregating legal or circumstantial indicators.

Several measures of government transparency have indeed sought to narrow the scope of indicators and focus on the actual release and flow of data and information from government officials ( [16, 40, 41]). Data availability indicators refer to surveys of government information published (primarily) electronically, or data reported to international organizations (see also [3]). Most notable among these is perhaps the index developed by Hollyer et al. [16] which maps the extent to which states comply with requests from the World Bank to release indicators that together make up the World Development Indicator (WDIs). While a significant contribution in its own right, and certainly an important indication of a state’s ability to collect and willingness to release data, the Hollyer et al. (henceforth HRV) indicator is not entirely suited to exploring the link between transparency and corruption for two reasons. First the HRV-index does not necessarily capture whether the government publishes information that can allow citizens to detect abuses. The indicators included in the WDI span a wide range of policy areas as well as economic conditions and from a range of market spheres.Footnote 4 Second, given the extensive span and the high-resolution nature of the indicators included in the WDI, it is likely that the HRV-index taps not only into a state’s willingness to collect and publish statistics, but its ability to do so in a broad range of policy sectors, and hence into government capacity. Tracking and measuring such a range of conditions presumes effective state presence in virtually all spheres of society. While useful for examining the link between government openness and phenomena that are exogenous to the state – such as for example aid donors’ willingness to allocate funds to a country – these broad transparency indicators are less useful for understanding the link between transparency and phenomena endogenous to government operations.

Our conceptualization and measurement of transparency seek to take these challenges into account in order to lay the groundwork for investigating more fine-grained theoretical claims. It specifies both the purpose and the principals and thus uses a narrower and more theoretically founded definition and measurement of transparency. It focuses specifically on the necessary and de facto elements of transparency for detecting government abuses, such as whistle blower protection, and the ability of actors outside the government to attain the information needed to assess performance. Although expert judgments are subject to problems of their own [42], they offer the advantage that they capture not only de jure but also de facto conditions.Footnote 5

Transparency for government probity: Fiscal openness and exposure of abuses

The conceptualization and measure of transparency for government probity introduced here capture two main dimensions of transparency argued to be relevant to containing and curbing corruption: fiscal openness and likelihood of exposure of abuses. These two aspects in combination capture the extent to which the public has access to information relevant to detecting venality. Fiscal openness is defined as the information that the government releases, electronically or in other forms, needed to track the flow of revenues and expenditures. It encompasses both the extent to which citizens can demand and receive information not published proactively, as well as that published routinely by government.

The Quality of Government expert survey included two questions designed to capture this dimension of transparency, the first asking experts to evaluate whether citizens and media actors can track the flow of government revenues and expenditures in their country. A second question asked experts to rate whether government documents and records are open to public access.

The second dimension, likelihood of exposure of abuses, depends primarily on the ability and willingness of actors inside the government to report any abuses they witness, which is largely a function of the whistleblowing protections in place. Whistle blowing in the public sector has, compared to transparency more generally, primarily been studied by legal scholars. Miceli and Near [43] define whistle blowing as “the disclosure by organization members (former or current) of illegal, immoral or illegitimate practices under the control of their employers, to persons or organizations that may be able to effect action” (see also [44,42,46]). Whistle-blower protections allow individuals to disclose information despite their individual connection to, and vulnerability to retaliation from, those in higher positions of power.

Specific whistleblower protection laws have been established in over 30 countries, while in other countries whistleblower protection is regulated through labor laws and laws related to public sector employment. These legal provisions vary in the extent to which they discourage the release of information to external actors (the media), whether they stipulate rewards for exposing abuses and whether protection from retaliation is circumscribed if it is deemed that whistle-blowers did not act in good faith [47]. The countries that have adopted more comprehensive whistleblower protection laws include the UK, South Africa, Ghana, Canada, Japan, New Zealand, and the United States [48, 49]. Sweden also has strong protections, granted through the world’s oldest freedom of press act, which give civil servants the right to anonymously report misdeeds in the public sector, and prohibit journalists from revealing the identity of sources under penalty of law. The survey asked experts to evaluate the overall likelihood that civil servants would experience negative repercussions if they engaged in whistle blowing.

Analytical approach and data

The empirical analyses seek to determine whether there is a link between transparency and corruption independent of other institutions or attributes of government and societal conditions. A correlation with corruption suggests convergent validity of the measure, and the fact that the correlation is independent of other factors indicates that we are capturing something that is distinct from the efficiency and capacity of the state more generally, i.e. divergent validity [50]. Since we believe that existing measures of transparency may partly capture state attributes outside the conceptual scope of transparency, we argue that evidence is still lacking as to whether an independent association exists. It is plausible that any observed association between transparency measures and government corruption may be due to the broad scope of measures used to measure both of these, which might result in false positives. Alternately, however, it is possible that existing measures are so noisy as to obscure a true association. Measures of transparency that tap into attributes of the state other than transparency may actually fail to capture the more relevant and operative aspects of transparency for reducing corruption, and a true association may become undetectable once these are controlled for. The analyses therefore examine the link between the measure we propose here and various measures of corruption, first in bivariate analyses and then under control for attributes of the state and society into which broader transparency measures may tap. The models taken together thus aim to examine whether transparency is linked to corruption independent of other factors.

The data are collected through a global survey of public administration experts, carried out in 2014. In addition to measuring our concept of transparency, the survey includes 59 additional questions on a range of topics related to bureaucratic quality, autonomy and the functioning of the state. Experts were identified by contacting public administration organizations affiliated with the United Nations Public Administration Network, professional networks, the academic literature and university websites. 7096 were sent the link to the questionnaire, of which 1294, or 18.2% submitted completed responses. The mean number of respondents per country in the dataset is 8.1 but some have as few as one expert. Only countries with at least 3 expert responses are included in the analyses below. One of the main concerns with expert surveys is individual level bias. An evaluative review of the data has analyzed individual level variation in experts’ assessments and concludes that “…estimates for a particular country are not determined by the make-up of the group of experts who provided assessments” [51].Footnote 6

The survey included three questions, combined into a transparency index capturing the dimensions of transparency discussed above. Experts were asked to rate to what extent they feel the following statements – the first two of which relate to fiscal openness, the third to the likelihood of exposure of abuses – applied to the country in question (1 = not at all; 7 = to a very large extent)Footnote 7:

  • Citizens and media actors can track the flow of government revenues and expenditures

  • Government documents and records are open to public access

  • Public sector employees risk severe negative consequences if they pass on information about abuses of public power to the media

In the empirical analyses all values are coded so that higher values mean more transparency.

Figures 1 and 2 show the transparency scores for OECD and non-OECD countries respectively. The country scores for the two component indicators shown in figures A1–A4 in the Appendix. Wicpossibility of tracking fiscal flows, the estimates plotted in the figures seem plausible. Many of the countries that cluster in the upper end of the transparency scale have long-standing traditions of transparency (Sweden, Finland, Iceland) or have recently taken large steps towards increasing their level of transparency (Chile and Costa Rica). Chile’s access to information law surpasses international standards in terms of the strength of legal guarantees and protections offered to citizens, suggesting a normative climate of transparency and openness. At the other end of the transparency scale, countries such as Japan, Guatemala, Eritrea, Algeria or Zimbabwe rank among the lowest of all the countries in the sample.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Transparency scores for OECD countries

Fig. 2
figure 2

Transparency scores for non-OECD countries

We compare the association of our measure of transparency to a variety of corruption measures, to that of two significant recent attempts to measure transparency: The HRV index [16] and Williams’ [70] measure of information transparency. Hollyer et al. [16] measures governments collection and release of economic and societal data, and relies on a Bayesian item response (IRT) model, which treats transparency as a latent predictor of the reporting or non-reporting of data in the World Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI) data series, including 240 variables collected by the WDI over time. The resulting index contains 125 countries covering a period from 1980 to 2010.Footnote 8 Williams’ index of information transparency [70] covers the same time span but uses data from 29 sources, with scores being derived for more than 190 countries. The component indicators capture the quantity of economic, social and financial information (very similar to the HRV-index), as well as the quality and processes generating economic, financial and social data, and information infrastructure.Footnote 9

Corruption measures

The corruption measures used range from narrow to broad narrow and broad, with the narrow measures capturing two distinct forms of corruption: petty (bribe-paying) and grand (irregular payments and diversion of funds). The former builds on the 8 questions from Transparency International’s Global Corruption Barometer (GCB) regarding whether or not a surveyed member of the public or someone in their household has paid a bribe in the past 12 months for various services. These questions are combined with one question from the World Economic Forum’s (WEF) Executive Opinion Survey, which asks executives how common it is that firms have to make irregular payments.Footnote 10 The measure of grand corruption also builds on two measures from the World Economic Forum’s Executive Opinion Survey that capture whether government shows favoritism when granting contracts, and the prevalence with which officials divert public funds to companies, individuals, or groups due to corruption [52]. We also examine whether transparency measures relate to a broad and widely used measure of corruption, namely the World Bank’s control of corruption measure.Footnote 11

Control variables

In our analysis, we explore the association between transparency and corruption under control for confounding factors to determine if an association exists independent of a country’s overall level of political development. We therefore control for democracy and bureaucratic quality in order to capture the related phenomena of accountability (including participation) and state capacity. To capture the level of state capacity we use the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) indicator of Bureaucratic Quality, which rates the extent to which government bureaucracies are autonomous from political pressure and recruit professional and qualified personnel to the civil service. These aspects of bureaucratic quality have been shown to correlate very strongly with the ability of the state to deliver services in a broad range of areas as well as the state’s ability to compile and publish statistics [54]. To capture democracy, we use the Boix et al. [55] dichotomous measure, which classifies countries as democracies if they hold free and fair elections and satisfy a threshold level of suffrage.Footnote 12

The analyses also control for indicators of of modernization or development such as GDP/capita (a logged measure from the Gleiditch Expanded Trade and GDP Data, [56]) and education (UNESCO gross enrollment data). The high correlation between government quality and economic development is, according to Treisman [42] “by far the strongest and most consistent finding” in empirical work (see also [42, 57, 58]). We also control for ethnic fractionalization using the measure developed by Alesina et al. [59], since more polarized societies are more prone to competitive rent seeking ( [60,54,62]: [63]) which may affect the quality of government institutions. Finally, the number of women in government may tap into both concepts since it may indicate a general inclusiveness of the political system [64,58,66].

Results

In this section we evaluate the utility of different conceptualizations and measurements of transparency for exploring the association between transparency for corruption mitigation. Numerous studies suggest that transparency is associated with lower levels of corruption; ([3, 6, 13, 17, 30, 33, 67,61,69]), yet we have argued that the measures of transparency used may yield misleading results.

Tables 2 and 3 show the link between three different measures of transparency, our own as well as those advanced by Williams’ [70] and Hollyer et al. [16] respectively, with three different measures of corruption. Table 2 shows the associations without controls and Table 3 with controls. All of the transparency measures have been rescaled to range from 0 to 1 so that the estimates show the total effect of each.

Table 2 Associations between transparency indices and various forms of corruption
Table 3 Associations between transparency and various forms of corruption with controls

The three measures of corruption capture petty, grand and the World Bank’s measure of control of corruption (inverted), an aggregate index on overall levels of corruption. The models without controls (Table 2) reveal that all of the transparency measures correlate with all of three corruption measures, and that the total effects do not differ substantially depending on which transparency measure is used. Once controls are entered into the model, however, the association between transparency and corruption does indeed vary depending on the indicator of transparency used (Table 3). Model 1 shows that the QoG transparency index is significantly negatively associated with the extent to which citizens’ and business executives pay bribes to government institutions. Model 2 shows that QoG transparency is also negatively associated with grand corruption, defined as collusion among elites that involves major public sector projects, procurement and large financial benefits ([33]: 27). Thus the QoG measure of transparency is negatively associated with both petty and grand corruption, and regardless of whether measures are based on elites and ordinary citizens’ self reported experiences or perceptions. Model 3 shows that QoG transparency is also negatively associated with the World Bank’s corruption index that captures aggregate levels of corruption using a large number of component indicators. While the estimates are considerably weaker with controls in the models, the estimates remain statistically significant, suggesting that our measure of government transparency indeed does have an independent association with corruption.

Comparing the first three models with the remaining six lends some credence to our claims that existing measures of transparency may tap into attributes of the state that extend beyond transparency itself. Models 4–6 show that the association between the HRV index and petty corruption is negative, but is instead positive with grand corruption with controls in the model. The association with the control of corruption is not significant. While the HRV transparency index captures data that is relevant for demands for accountability or the functioning of democracy, this form of transparency may not lend itself as well to the detection of corruption in the management of public resources. Thus, even if data availability on market and societal conditions in general may be a function of democracy that also facilitates accountability, it may not suffice to detect corruption or the extraction of rents, which could remain relatively hidden even among widely published statistics. Models 7–9 show that the Williams’ information transparency index is negatively associated with petty corruption, but is not associated with the other measures of corruption when controls are included.

In addition, the results also show that the level of democracy is generally insignificant when accounting for the effect of transparency. GDP/capita, share of women in the lower house and the level of state capacity are in almost all the models significantly negatively associated with corruption.

Taken together, the results suggest that the association between transparency and corruption is not stable across indicators, and that the association between transparency and corruption may be contingent upon the extent to which these measures tap into political development and state capacity more generally. Our results suggest that the QoG transparency indicator is more consistently associated with the different types of corruption included than other indicators developed and used in recent research.

Conclusions

Transparency, despite a surge of attention in policy and academic arenas, has received insufficient rigorous theoretical attention and has suffered from considerable conceptual stretching. Indicators agglomerated into indexes tend to be drawn from disparate areas and incorporate contiguous concepts such as accountability and underlying qualities of good government and state capacity. Much like concepts such as democracy or good governance, transparency is often discussed in conjunction with a host of attributes considered integral to good government, so much so that they are seldom disaggregated theoretically and empirically. A transparent organization is not by definition subject to strong sanctioning mechanisms, nor by necessity invites constituents or stakeholders to participate, provide input, and express grievances. A first step in the analytical dissection of transparency is therefore to disentangle it from other complementary aspects of good governance, as well as from the societal preconditions that shape whether transparency has the expected positive effects.

In investigations of transparency, using broad measures characterized by conceptual dispersion in all likelihood will result in false positives (type I errors), because measures bleed conceptually into one another. Alternatively, a measure which fails to capture the most relevant and operative aspects of a phenomenon may fail to reveal an associations which in reality exists.

This paper has sought to contribute a general theoretical framework that might assist in developing measures of transparency suited to exploring more specific claims about these positive effects, an exercise which, we argue, requires paying attention to the intended use or purpose of the information, as well as the intended user, or principal. Moreover, the paper introduces new data covering 105 countries and an index that captures the type of transparency likely to contribute to the control of corruption. The empirical analyses suggest that transparency indeed does have a robust and independent association with various forms of corruption.

Moving forward, we see a need for more in depth explorations of heterogeneity of the effects of transparency on corruption, either using the measure presented here or other more fine-grained measures. Previous research, including our own, has presented evidence that transparency in contexts with high levels of corruption can breed political resignation, especially if the mechanisms for exercising accountability are weak or lacking [1, 12, 29], and that the likelihood of exposure may vary between different forms of corruption [72]. More research is needed on the contextual conditions needed for transparency to reduce corruption.