Skip to main content
Log in

A Behavioral Theory of Electoral Structure

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Political Behavior Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Why are party systems in modern democracies so essentially robust? We theorize patterns of electoral competition as the outcome of a struggle between entropy and structure. Forces of entropy entail idiosyncratic voting behavior guided by subjective evaluations, while forces of structure entail coordinated behavior emerging from objective aspects of party preference. Our model locates determinants of party preference on a continuum spanning subjective and objective concerns. Entropy is endemic but elections for nationwide executive office periodically prime objective concerns, reinstating structure in party systems. We demonstrate the cyclical pulse of national elections in a comparative analysis of pseudo-randomized survey data from the European Election Studies since 1989. We also show how feedback from differently-sized party systems consolidates different working equilibria.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is not evident in analyses that treat parties separately, but our research design considers generic party support, also avoiding the tautology that people support large parties by definition.

  2. But note that objectivity does not imply immobility. Demographic characteristics surely change and party systems, like all of society, have to adapt. However, this is a long-term process that gives parties ample time to react or even be proactive. Objectivity, in contrast, is a more immediate force that reproduces structure at the relatively fast rhythm of the electoral cycle.

  3. A possible, complementary, extension of this argument is that citizens have a preference for stable majority government as such and vote accordingly (e.g., LeDuc 1977).

  4. Note that first-order-ness is a measure in its own right, not an instrument for unmeasured motivations. So the question of meeting an exclusion restriction does not arise.

  5. Indeed, enlightened preferences theory provides another way of viewing our expectation that first-order structuring extends into the electoral cycle on both sides of an FOE.

  6. The idea that voters more centrist than the politicians they elect try to ensure centrist policies by voting at midterm to balance the outcome of the previous presidential election. For comparative perspectives, see Carrubba and Timpone (2005), Marsh (2007) and Kedar (2009).

  7. Each perspective has an early precursor. Pedersen (1979) showed how more parties increase the entropic potential of electoral volatility, and Hirschman (1970, 26ff.) argued that competition solidifies market structures if consumers switch back and forth between limited suppliers.

  8. The data and replication code are available at doi:10.7910/DVN/QZVK4B.

  9. Several electoral contexts had missing values for one or another required variable. Such values were imputed in the stacked dataset if all other required variables were measured.

  10. Perceptions of party positions generally suffer from rationalization bias as respondents seek closeness to preferred parties and contrast to less preferred parties. Importantly, such bias would be stronger around national elections and thus works against our hypotheses, which expect subjective variables to have stronger effect around midterm.

  11. No election is coded exactly 0 because, if an FOE is held on the same day as the EP election, that context is coded 1 on Cycle (a full cycle has elapsed since the previous FOE). This applies to nine contexts (five of which involve Luxembourg, see Online Appendix), which allow us to demonstrate that the cycle curves are not mere inter-election phenomena; they extend into first-order territory.

  12. Interactions with higher-order polynomials of Cycle did not yield additional insights.

  13. Note that random respondent intercepts enforce a focus on within-individual comparison, much as conditional logit does in the estimation of discrete choice models.

  14. Our model contains no party level, so party size is implicitly an effect at the lowest level. An additional level would have overloaded an already complex model. However, in a simpler model estimated for only one year, party size had a stronger and more highly significant effect when an explicit party level was defined, so our simplification of the hierarchical structure is conservative.

  15. The cyclical effect of party size is clearly asymmetric. This is at least partly because size does not measure the current state of affairs but the state of affairs at the time of the preceding FOE. This means that size “ages.” Unlike other variables that are continuously updated, its functionality as an indicator decreases through time. Once we jointly consider the instrumental effect and its decrease over time, we arrive at the picture displayed in Fig. 2: a strong effect at the start, a weak effect at midterm and an in-between effect at the end. We may additionally be seeing evidence of a long-term decline in the coherence of European party systems (see below).

  16. Note, however, that our estimate of the general level of the effect of social structure is conservative (see Online Appendix).

  17. We also tested for cyclical trends in the general level of independent variables. No such patterns were found. This means that the findings in Table 1 are not due to a composition effect in the number of people expressing partisanship or ascribing competence.

  18. The correlation of TPD (a context-level measure) and party size (a party-level measure) is a mere 0.167, so that collinearity is not a concern.

  19. We resists the temptation to interpret the reversed cycle theoretically because this finding is largely based on extrapolation—after all, there is only one case of TPD = 1 in our data (Malta 2009). The extrapolation is certainly based on a strong interaction in the data at large, but estimating the exact function for TPD = 1 is beyond our means.

References

  • Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided government and the economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Andersen, R., Tilley, J., & Heath, A. F. (2005). Political knowledge and enlightened preferences: Party choice through the electoral cycle. British Journal of Political Science, 35(2), 285–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. (1988). Elections, coalitions, and legislative outcomes. American Political Science Review, 82(2), 405–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bargsted, M. A., & Kedar, O. (2009). Coalition-targeted Duvergerian voting: How expectations affect voter choice under proportional representation. American Journal of Political Science, 53(2), 307–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck, U. (1992). Risk society: Towards a new modernity. London: SAGE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bendor, J., Diermeier, D., Siegel, D. A., & Ting, M. M. (2011). A behavioral theory of elections. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolleyer, N., & Bytzek, E. (2013). Origins of party formation and new party success in advanced democracies. European Journal of Political Research, 52(6), 773–796.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bølstad, J., Dinas, E., & Riera, P. (2013). Tactical voting and party preferences: A test of cognitive dissonance theory. Political Behavior, 35(3), 429–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowler, S., Grofman, B., & Blais, A. (2009). The United States: A case of Duvergerian equilibrium. In B. Grofman, A. Blais, & S. Bowler (Eds.), Duverger’s law of plurality voting (pp. 135–146). New York: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A. (1960). Surge and decline: A study of electoral change. Public Opinion Quarterly, 24(3), 397–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. E. (1993). The presidential pulse of congressional elections. Lexington: University Press of Kentucky.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A., Converse, P. E., Miller, W. E., & Stokes, D. E. (1960). The American voter. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A., & Valen, H. (1961). Party identification in Norway and the United States. Public Opinion Quarterly, 25(4), 505–525.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrubba, C. J., & Timpone, R.J. (2005). Explaining vote switching across first- and second-order elections: Evidence from Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 38(3), 260–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casal Bértoa, F., & Weber, T. 2016. Party system change in times of crisis. Paper for the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Philadelphia, PA.

  • Converse, P. E. (1966). The concept of a normal vote. In A. Campbell, P. E. Converse, W. E. Miller, & D. E. Stokes (Eds.), Elections and the political order (pp. 9–39). New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W. (1997). Making votes count: Strategic coordination in the world’s electoral systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, R. J., Flanagan, S. C., & Beck, P. A. (Eds.). (1984). Electoral change in advanced industrial democracies: Realignment or dealignment?. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dassonneville, R., & Hooghe, M. 2011. Mapping electoral volatility in Europe: an analysis of trends in electoral volatility in European democracies since 1945. Paper for the European Conference on Comparative Electoral Research, Sofia, Bulgaria.

  • De Sio, L., Franklin, M. N., & Weber, T. (2016). The risks and opportunities of Europe: How issue yield explains (non-)reactions to the financial crisis. Electoral Studies, 44, 483–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Vries, C. E., Hakhverdian, A., & Lancee, B. (2013). The dynamics of voters’ left/right identification: The role of economic and cultural attitudes. Political Science Research and Methods, 1(2), 223–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deegan-Krause, K. (2007). New dimensions of political cleavage. In R. J. Dalton & H.-D. Klingemann (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Political Behavior (pp. 538–556). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dinas, E. (2012). The formation of voting habits. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion & Parties, 22(4), 431–456.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinas, E. (2014). Does choice bring loyalty? Electoral participation and the development of party identification. American Journal of Political Science, 58(2), 449–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Druckman, J. N., & Lupia, A. (2000). Preference formation. Annual Review of Political Science, 3, 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duverger, M. (1954). Political parties. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enyedi, Z. (2008). The social and attitudinal basis of political parties: Cleavage politics revisited. European Review, 16(3), 287–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Enyedi, Z. (2014). The discreet charm of political parties. Party Politics, 20(2), 194–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erikson, R. S., & Wlezien, C. (2012). The timeline of presidential elections: How campaigns do (and do not) matter. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G., & De Graaf, N. D. (Eds.). (2013). Political choice matters: Explaining the strength of class and religious cleavages in cross-national perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. P. (1992). Divided government. New York: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Franklin, M. N. (2004). Voter turnout and the dynamics of electoral competition in established democracies since 1945. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Franklin, M. N., & Hobolt, S. B. (2011). The legacy of lethargy: How elections to the European Parliament depress turnout. Electoral Studies, 30(1), 67–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franklin, C. H., & Jackson, J. E. (1983). The dynamics of party identification. American Political Science Review, 77(4), 957–973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franklin, M. N., Mackie, T., & Valen, H. (Eds.). (1992). Electoral change. Responses to evolving social and attitudinal structures in Western Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuchs, D., & Klingemann, H.-D. (1989). The left–right schema. In M. K. Jennings, J. W. van Deth, S. H. Barnes, D. Fuchs, F. J. Heunks, R. Inglehart, M. Kaase, H.-D. Klingemann, & J. Thomassen (Eds.), Continuities in political action (pp. 203–234). New York: de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelman, A., & King, G. (1993). Why are American presidential election campaign polls so variable when votes are so predictable? British Journal of Political Science, 23(4), 409–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, A. S., Green, D. P., & Shachar, R. (2003). Voting may be habit-forming: Evidence from a randomized field experiment. American Journal of Political Science, 47(3), 540–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomez, R. (2013). All that you can (not) leave behind: Habituation and vote loyalty in the Netherlands. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion & Parties, 23(2), 134–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Górecki, M. A. (2013). Electoral context, habit-formation and voter turnout: A new analysis. Electoral Studies, 32(1), 140–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grotz, F. & Weber, T. 2016. Wahlsysteme und Sitzverteilung im Europäischen Parlament. [trans. Electoral systems and seat distribution in the European Parliament.] In H. Schoen & B. Weßels (Eds.) Wahlen und Wähler: Analysen aus Anlass der Bundestagswahl 2013 (pp. 493–515). Wiesbaden: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, voice, and loyalty. Responses to decline in firms, organizations, and states. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hix, S., & Marsh, M. (2007). Punishment or protest? Understanding European Parliament elections. Journal of Politics, 69(2), 495–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobolt, S. B., Spoon, J.-J., & Tilley, J. (2009). A vote against Europe? Explaining defection at the 1999 and 2004 European parliament elections. British Journal of Political Science, 39(1), 93–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Honaker, J., King, G., & Blackwell, M. 2007. Amelia II: A program for missing data. Retrieved June 23, 2007, from http://gking.harvard.edu/amelia/.

  • Jennings, M. K., & Markus, G. B. (1984). Partisan orientations over the long haul: Results from the three-wave political socialization panel study. The American Political Science Review, 78(4), 1000–1018.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karp, J.A., & Hobolt, S.B., eds. 2010. Voters and Coalition Governments. Symposium of Electoral Studies 29(3), 299–391.

  • Katz, R. S., & Mair, P. (1995). Changing models of party organization and party democracy: The emergence of the cartel party. Party Politics, 1(1), 5–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kedar, O. (2009). Voting for policy, not parties: How voters compensate for power sharing. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kedar, O. (2012). Voter choice and parliamentary politics: An emerging research agenda. British Journal of Political Science, 42(3), 537–553.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirchheimer, O. (1966). The transformation of Western European party systems. In J. LaPalombara & M. Weiner (Eds.), Political parties and political development (pp. 177–200). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kriesi, H., Grande, E., Lachat, R., Dolezal, M., Bornschier, S., & Frey, T. (2008). West European politics in the age of globalization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • LeDuc, L. (1977). Political behaviour and the issue of majority government in two federal elections. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 10(2), 311–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1994). Electoral systems and party systems. A study of twenty-seven democracies 1945–1990. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (2012). Patterns of democracy: Government forms and performance in thirty-six countries (2nd ed.). New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipset, S.M., & Rokkan, S. 1967. Cleavage structures, party systems and voter alignments: An introduction. In Party systems and voter alignments: Cross-national perspectives, (pp. 1–64). New York: The Free Press.

  • Mair, P. (1997). Party system change: Approaches and interpretations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsh, M. (2007). European Parliament elections and losses by governing parties. In W. van der Brug & C. van der Eijk (Eds.), European Elections and Domestic Politics (pp. 51–72). Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsh, M., & Mikhaylov, S. (2010). European Parliament elections and EU governance. Living Reviews in European Governance, 5(4), 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meredith, M. (2009). Persistence in political participation. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 4(3), 187–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milnor, A. J., & Franklin, M. N. (1973). Patterns of opposition behavior in modern legislatures. In A. Kornberg (Ed.), Legislatures in comparative perspective (pp. 421–446). New York: McKay.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mudde, C. (2014). Fighting the system? Populist radical right parties and party system change. Party Politics, 20(2), 217–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullainathan, S., & Washington, E. (2009). Sticking with your vote: Cognitive dissonance and political attitudes. Applied Economics, 1(1), 86–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oppenhuis, E., van der Eijk, C., & Franklin, M. (1996). The party context: Outcomes. In C. van der Eijk & M. N. Franklin (Eds.), Choosing Europe? (pp. 287–305). Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Panebianco, A. (1988). Political parties: Organization and power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, C., & Weber, T. (2011). Cross-cutting issues and party strategy in the European Union. Comparative Political Studies, 44(4), 383–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedersen, M. N. (1979). The dynamics of European party systems: Changing patterns of electoral volatility. European Journal of Political Research, 7(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plutzer, E. (2002). Becoming a habitual voter: Inertia, resources, and growth in young adulthood. American Political Science Review, 96(1), 41–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rae, D. W. (1967). The political consequences of electoral laws. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reif, K. (1984). National electoral cycles and European elections 1979 and 1984. Electoral Studies, 3(3), 244–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reif, K., & Schmitt, H. (1980). Nine second-order national elections—A conceptual framework for the analysis of European election results. European Journal of Political Research, 8(1), 3–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rokkan, S. (1970). Citizens, elections, parties: Approaches to the comparative study of the processes of development. Oslo: Universitetsforlaget.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossiter, C. (1956). The American presidency. New York: Harvest.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. (1976). Parties and party systems: A framework for analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shachar, R. (2003). Party loyalty as habit formation. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18(3), 251–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shamir, M. (1984). Are western party systems “frozen”? A comparative dynamic analysis. Comparative Political Studies, 17(1), 35–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science, 23(1), 27–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmel, G. (1908). Soziologie. Untersuchungen über die Formen der Vergesellschaftung. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. S. (1989). Seats and votes: The effects and determinants of electoral systems. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toole, J. (2000). Government formation and party system stabilization in East Central Europe. Party Politics, 6(4), 441–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tufte, E. R. (1975). Determinants of the outcomes of Congressional midterm elections. American Political Science Review, 69(3), 812–826.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van der Brug, W., van der Eijk, C., & Franklin, M. N. (2007). The economy and the vote: Economic conditions and elections in fifteen countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • van der Eijk, C., & Franklin, M. N. (Eds.). (1996). Choosing Europe? The European electorate and national politics in the face of union. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van der Eijk, C., Franklin, M. N., & Marsh, M. (1996a). What voters teach us about Europe-wide elections: What Europe-wide elections teach us about voters. Electoral Studies, 15(2), 149–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van der Eijk, C., Franklin, M. N., & Oppenhuis, E. (1996b). The strategic context: Party choice. In C. van der Eijk & M. N. Franklin (Eds.), Choosing Europe? (pp. 332–365). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • van der Eijk, C., van der Brug, W., Kroh, M., & Franklin, M. N. (2006). Rethinking the dependent variable in voting behavior: On the measurement and analysis of electoral utilities. Electoral Studies, 25(3), 424–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, T. (2007). Campaign effects and second-order cycles: A top-down approach to European Parliament elections. European Union Politics, 8(4), 509–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, T. (2009). When the cat is away the mice will play: Why elections to the European Parliament are about Europe after all. Politique Européenne, 28, 53–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, T. (2011). Exit, voice, and cyclicality: A micrologic of midterm effects in European Parliament elections. American Journal of Political Science, 55(4), 907–922.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Early versions of this paper were presented at APSA 2010 and MPSA 2011 as well as in talks at Australian National University, the European University Institute, Nuffield College Oxford, Temple University, Trinity College Dublin, University of British Columbia and University of Houston. We thank the participants for their helpful comments and in particular Matt Barreto, Fabrizio Bernardi, Cees van der Eijk, Anand Shastri, Laura Stoker, Bernhard Wessels, Christopher Wlezien, and the anonymous reviewers.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Till Weber.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 143 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Weber, T., Franklin, M.N. A Behavioral Theory of Electoral Structure. Polit Behav 40, 831–856 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-017-9425-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-017-9425-5

Keywords

Navigation