Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Crisis and contract breach: The domestic and international determinants of expropriation

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we address how external factors shape government decisions to break or uphold contracts, specifically focusing on how economic shocks and support from multilateral financial institutions shape leader decisions to expropriate from investors. Contrary to conventional wisdom and much of the existing scholarship, we argue that governments are less likely to expropriate from investors during periods of economic crisis since governments become more sensitive to the reputational costs of expropriating. We also argue that governments are sensitive to the levers other governments may use to punish for expropriation, such as withholding IMF and World Bank funding. We test these theories using a dataset of investment expropriations and case studies of thirty-four investment disputes that were resolved pre-claim. Our econometric analysis suggests that expropriations of foreign investment are less common during periods of crisis, and that countries under IMF agreements or borrowing from the World Bank are less likely to expropriate. Our thirty-four case studies, which substantiate the role of government reputation and multilateral pressure, support our statistical results.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For an overview see Jensen (2006).

  2. One strategy is to engage in joint ventures with local firms. See Henisz (2000).

  3. For an overview see Jensen et al. (2012).

  4. For an overview see Rudra (2008).

  5. Jensen (2003) and Li and Resnick (2003), for example, examine the impact of democratic institutions on FDI flows. While Jensen (2003) argues that democratic institutions increase FDI flows, Li and Resnick (2003) show that this increase is through democracies having a stronger rule of law. Other aspects of democracies, for example stronger anti-monopoly laws, reduce FDI flows.

  6. Kerner (2009) provides an excellent overview and empirical test of these signaling and constraining aspects of BITs. See Guzman (2006) on the diffusion of BITs. See Yackee (2008) and Allee and Peinhardt (2010) on the variation in dispute mechanisms across BITs. See UNCTAD (1998), Neumayer and Spess (2005), Salacuse and Sullivan (2005), and Kerner (2009), and Lee and Johnston (2016) for published studies of the impact of BITs on FDI.

  7. More recently, Tomz and Wright (2010) model both sovereign bond investment and FDI to examine governments’ incentives to expropriate/default foreign investment. Consistent with Cole and English (1991), they argue that governments are more likely to expropriate during good economic times if they are risk neutral, and during bad times if they are risk averse. On the other hand, leaders are more likely to default during bad economic times, independent of their risk acceptance level.

  8. If, for example, a government wishes to privatize after a crisis, they may be less likely to jeopardize future investment by expropriating.

  9. “Washington Ruling Makes NAIA 3 Use Illegal,” Inquirer.net 2011.

  10. Business scholars discuss numerous ways that avoiding expropriation can create financial market benefits. They find, for example, that protections against expropriations are associated with more investments (per investment opportunities) (Wurgler 2000), an expansion of the financial market (La et al. 2002), more valuable stock markets (La et al. 1997), and listed firms that are larger (Kumar et al. 1999), more numerous (La et al. 1999), more valuable (Claessens et al. 2002; La et al. 2002), pay greater dividend payments (La et al. 2000), and have lower private benefits of control (Zingales 1994; Nenova 1999). See Shleifer and Wolfenzon (2002) for a more comprehensive review. Given the capital scarcity during a crisis, expropriations may trigger multiple types of broader financial market costs.

  11. According to de Paoli et al. (2006), there are two costs of default: reduced access to future finance and output loss (because domestic firms are also unable to borrow). They argue that banking crises and currency crises exacerbate the output loss during default because domestic banks cannot function as intermediaries and provide credit as before and currency crises increase governments’ fixed debt. They call this output loss broader financial costs.

  12. 12 For interested readers, in the Online Appendix we formalize this logic with a game theoretical model. The model makes three assumptions: 1) that revenue is more valuable in a crisis than in normal times, 2) that there is more uncertainty in the expected expropriation payoff than simply keeping the investment as is, and 3) that a government may face a further drop if additional market costs accompany a crisis-time expropriation. As stated on page 9 of the theoretical Appendix , the comparative statics analysis finds that the incidence of expropriation will decrease during a crisis due to: long- and short-term costs (e.g. from currency and bond markets), the chance of spillover effects, the prospect of future investment loss, and the possibility (even remote) of a larger downturn.

  13. Wellhausen (2015b) also notes that home governments do not always follow through these threats because high FDI national diversity in the host country reduces the home government’s diplomatic leverage.

  14. 14 For interested readers, see the Online Appendix for a game theoretic derivation of this hypothesis.

  15. A list of these countries can be seen in the Online Appendix .

  16. Another often used database on financial crises is the Reinhart-Rogoff financial crises data. We choose the Laeven and Valencia data because the Reinhart-Rogoff data cover only 70 countries, including OECD countries which are not our focus.

  17. Thanks to an anonymous reviewer for this excellent suggestion. We also try numerous ways of calculating moving averages, including averaging from 3 to 10 years and using exponential weights, and the results remain largely unchanged.

  18. First, we operationalize crisis as a dichotomous indicator of financial crises. Second, as an alternative to a one-year lag, we test all models using a two-year lag. We also try another commonly used measure of economic crisis—an indicator of negative economic growth. The results remain robust when different measures or lags of crises are used.

  19. Here we only use the original crisis variable, and not the moving average for simplicity.

  20. For instance, in Ethiopia 1975 alone, there were 25 expropriation cases. To reduce the potential bias driven by these extreme cases, we also use a dichotomous measure indicating whether there was at least one expropriation event, and perform a logit model. The results remain unchanged, which can be seen in the supplemental files.

  21. These four arrangements are IMF Standby Arrangement, IMF Extended Fund Facility Arrangement, IMF Structural Adjustment Facility Arrangement, and IMF Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility Arrangement.

  22. We add a value of one to this variable before taking logs to avoid negative values.

  23. It is well-known that unconditional MLE fixed-effects models may have the incidental parameter problem. Allison and Waterman (2002), however, show that negative binomial models with fixed effects (by including dummy variables) do not suffer from this bias. When we use a fixed-effects Poisson model (which is free from the incidental parameter problem) and correct the standard errors, the results remain unchanged.

  24. To make the interpretation easier, we rescale the moving average for the crisis variable such that the value equals 1 when there is one crisis in the previous year (and none in the seven years before last year). This is simply done by multiplying the moving average by 4.5.

  25. An alternative explanation is that countries that are more open to the global market may have more opportunities to expropriate foreign assets. This explanation, however, seems less plausible than the “opportunistic” explanation because long-term factors related to host-country property rights and trade policies, such as FDI and country fixed effects, are already controlled for in the model.

  26. In an earlier version of this paper, we also test the interactive effect between financial crisis and IMF support, but do not find any significant impact of their interaction.

  27. An earlier version of this paper included foreign aid as an independent variable to test the effect of another form of foreign support. Aid, however, is not a robust predictor of expropriation, probably because foreign aid is a more complex foreign policy tool that involves the donor country’s strategic considerations. Also, the collinearity of aid with other control variables and the inconsistent results across specifications suggest caution is required in interpreting these results.

  28. See Terza et al. (2008) and Wooldridge (2014) for a detailed discussion of the CF approach.

  29. The items included in the assets and liabilities categories change throughout this period. If the term of the borrowings was not defined, we took one tenth of the given amount to consider only short-term borrowings. We did the same for any charges accrued on debt. Starting in 1991 IDA did not provide a liabilities category. We construct it from payables and undistributed loans from statement of development resources tables. Dreher et al. (2017) use a similar strategy to create instruments for WB loans. They suggest using separate measurements for IBRD and IDA aid resources. In our main analysis we use a combined measurement of IBRD and IDA loans, and therefore we prefer to measure them similarly and create an aggregated WB measurement of aid resources.

  30. We did not include country and year fixed effects in the first stage logit model due to the possible incidental parameter problem (Greene 2004).

  31. The alternatives for count data are Poisson and negative binomial models. Wooldridge (1999), however, argues that the Poisson model is too restrictive and the negative binomial model can be complicated and may produce inconsistent results if some aspects of the distribution is misspecified. He argues that the quasi-Poisson model is the more robust. We use the quasi-Poisson model in the CF analysis, in particular, because it provided more consistent results across 1000 bootstrapped samples.

  32. All models, except for the logit model, include country fixed effects. The full table is presented in the Online Appendix .

  33. We corrected the standard errors using 1,000 bootstrap samples.

  34. The results of the logit model also offer strong support for the main hypothesis. We choose to report the results of the negative binomial model because the count variable offers more information than the binary variable.

  35. Interviews were facilitated by Daniel Villar, Former Lead Risk Management Specialist at MIGA and currently Principal Economist and Credit Risk Head at the World Bank. All interviews were conducted via phone in April and May 2013.

  36. We discuss these two cases later in this section.

  37. The election of Correa in Ecuador led to general calls for public ownership of water utilities. Although there was criticism of this operation by some local stakeholders, MIGA staff indicated that this dispute was less about the performance of the contract and more of an ideological commitment to public ownership in this sector.

  38. AES eventually agreed to renegotiate the power generation contract, but the highly favorable terms of the distribution contract are a potential future expropriation risk.

  39. The major issue with the cotton gin was that the company negotiated a contract that guaranteed minimum payments. Unfortunately, few farmers grew cotton (presumably growing opium instead) and the gin was largely unused. The government resisted providing payments to a company that was not producing cotton. Details on the project can be found here: http://www.miga.org/projects/index.cfm?pid=?661.

  40. Interviews with MIGA suggest that disputes in China and Kazakhstan are examples of this.

  41. Interviews with MIGA suggest Benin, Egypt, Kyrgyzstan, and Moldova fit this pattern.

References

  • Abiad, A., & Mody, A. (2005). Financial reform: What shakes it? What shapes it? American Economic Review, 95(1), 66–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allee, T., & Peinhardt, C. (2010). Delegating differences: Bilateral investment treaties and bargaining over dispute resolution provisions. International Studies Quarterly, 54(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allison, P.D., & Waterman, R.P. (2002). Fixed-Effects Negative binomial regression models. Sociological Methodology, 32(1), 247–265.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antzoulatos, A.A. (2000). On the determinants and resilience of bond flows to LDCs, 1990–1995. Journal of International Money and Finance, 19(3), 399–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biglaiser, G., & DeRouen, Jr. K. (2004). The expansion of neoliberal economic reforms in Latin America. International Studies Quarterly, 48(3), 561–578.

  • Biglaiser, G., Lee, H., Staats, J.L. (2016). The effects of the IMF on expropriation of foreign firms. The Review of International Organizations, 11(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broz, J., & Hawes, M.B. (2006). Lawrence congressional politics of financing the international monetary fund. International Organization, 60(2), 367–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bun, M.J.G., & Harrison, T.D. (2018). OLS And IV estimation of regression models including endogenous interaction terms. Econometric Reviews, 1–14.

  • Carter, B.E., Trimble, P.R., Bradley, C.A. (2003). International law, 4th edn. New York: Aspen Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christian, P., & Barrett, C.B. (2017). Revisiting the effect of food aid on conflict: A methodological caution. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 8171. Washington, DC.

  • Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J.P.H., Lang, L.H.P. (2002). Disentangling the incentive and entrenchment effects of large shareholdings. The Journal of Finance, 57(6), 2741–2771.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole, H.L., & English, W.B. (1991). Expropriation and direct investment. Journal of International Economics, 30(3-4), 201–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copelovitch, M.S. (2009). Master or Servant? Common Agency and the Political Economy of IMF Lending. International Studies Quarterly, 54(1), 49–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Paoli, B., Glenn, H., Saporta, V. (2006). Costs of sovereign default. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, 46(3), 297–307.

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen, A., & Easterly, W. (2001). Do crises induce reform? Simple empirical tests of conventional wisdom. Economics & Politics, 13(2), 129–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A. (2006). IMF And economic growth: The effects of programs, loans, and compliance with conditionality. World Development, 34(5), 769–788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Fuchs, A., Parks, B., Strange, A., Tierney, M.J. (2017). Aid, China, and Growth: Evidence from a New Global Development Finance Dataset. AidData Working Paper 46.

  • Duch, R.M., & Stevenson, R.T. (2008). The economic vote: How political and economic institutions condition election results. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Duncan, R. (2006). Price or politics? an investigation of the causes of expropriation. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 50(1), 85–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrett, G. (1998). Partisan politics in the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, B.A.T., Johnston, N.P., Kingsley, A.F. (2017). Even Constrained Governments Take: The Domestic Politics of Transfer and Expropriation Risks. Journal of Conflict Resolution. Online First.

  • Greene, W. (2004). Fixed effects and bias due to the incidental parameters problem in the Tobit model. Econometric reviews, 23(2), 125–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guriev, S., Kolotilin, A., Sonin, K. (2011). Determinants of nationalization in the oil sector: A theory and evidence from panel data. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 27(2), 301–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guzman, A.T. (2006). Competing for capital: the diffusion of bilateral investment treaties, 1960-2000. International Organization, 60(4), 811–846.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haggard, S., & Maxfield, S. (1996). The political economy of financial internationalization in the developing world. International Organization, 50(1), 35–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hajzler, C. (2012). Expropriation of foreign direct investments: sectoral patterns from 1993 to 2006. Review of World Economics, 148(1), 119–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, K.W. (2005). Tales from the dark side: Lessons learned from troubled investments. In West, G.T., & Moran, T.H. (Eds.) International Political Risk Management: Looking To The Future (pp. 12–29). Washington: World Bank.

  • Henisz, W.J. (2000). The institutional environment for multinational investment. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 16(2), 334–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N.M. (2003). Democratic governance and multinational corporations: Political regimes and inflows of foreign direct investment. International Organization, 57(3), 587–616.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N.M. (2004). Crisis, conditions, and capital: The effect of International Monetary Fund agreements on foreign direct investment inflows. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 48(2), 194–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N.M. (2006). Nation-states and the Multinational Corporation: A Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N.M. (2008). Political risk, democratic institutions, and foreign direct investment. Journal of Politics, 70(4), 1042–1052.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N.M., & Johnston, N.P. (2011). Political risk, reputation, and the resource curse. Comparative Political Studies, 44(6), 662–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, N.M., Biglaiser, G., Li, Q., Malesky, E., Pinto, P.M., Pinto, S.M., Staats, J.L. (2012). Politics and Foreign Direct Investment. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jodice, D.A. (1980). Sources of change in Third World regimes for foreign direct investment, 1968–1976. International Organization, 34(2), 177–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johns, L., & Wellhausen, R.L. (2016). Under one roof: Supply chains and the protection of foreign investment. American Political Science Review, 110(1), 31–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaminsky, G., & Schmukler, S.L. (2002). Emerging market instability: do sovereign ratings affect country risk and stock returns? The World Bank Economic Review, 16(2), 171–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerner, A. (2009). Why should I believe you? The costs and consequences of bilateral investment treaties. International Studies Quarterly, 53(1), 73–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C.P. (1996). Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises, 3rd edn. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, G., & Roberts, M.E. (2015). How robust standard errors expose methodological problems they do not fix, and what to do about it. Political Analysis, 23(2), 159–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kobrin, S. (1979). Political risk: a review and reconsideration. Journal of International Business Studies, 10(1), 67–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kobrin, S.J. (1980). Foreign enterprise and forced divestment in LDCs. International Organization, 34(1), 65–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kobrin, S.J. (1984). Expropriation as an attempt to control foreign firms in LDCs: trends from 1960 to 1979. International Studies Quarterly, 28(3), 329–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kriesi, H. (2012). The political consequences of the financial and economic crisis in Europe: Electoral punishment and popular protest. Swiss Political Science Review, 18(4), 518–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, K.B., Rajan, R.G., Zingales, L. (1999). What determines firm size? NBER working paper 7208 National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • La, P.R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. The Journal of Finance, 52(3), 1131–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La, P.R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world. Journal of Finance, 54(2), 471–517.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La, P.R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W. (2000). Agency problems and dividend policies around the world. The Journal of Finance, 55(1), 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La, P.R., Lopez-de Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R. (2002). Investor protection and corporate valuation. The Journal of Finance, 57(3), 1147–1170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laeven, L., & Valencia, F. (2008). Systemic banking crises: a new database. IMF Working Papers, 8224(200), 1–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang, V. (2016). The Economics of the Democratic Deficit: The Effect of IMF Programs on Inequality. Heidelberg University Discussion Paper.

  • Lee, C.-y., & Johnston, N.P. (2016). Improving reputation BIT by BIT: Bilateral investment treaties and foreign accountability. International Interactions, 42(3), 429–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck, M.S., & Stegmaier, M. (2000). Economic determinants of electoral outcomes. Annual Review of Political Science, 3(1), 183–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis-Beck, M.S., Stegmaier, M., Hans-Dieter, K. (2007). Economic Models of Voting. In Dalton, R.J. (Ed.) Oxford Handbook of Political Behaviour (pp. 519–537): Oxford University Press.

  • Li, Q. (2009). Democracy, autocracy, and expropriation of foreign direct investment. Comparative Political Studies, 42(8), 1098–1127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, Q, & Resnick, A. (2003). Reversal of fortunes: Democratic institutions and foreign direct investment inflows to developing countries. International Organization, 57(1), 175–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Michael, T. (2007). Reputation and international cooperation: Sovereign debt across three centuries princeton. NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • MIGA. (2012). 2012 Annual Report. Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency.

  • Min, H.-G., Lee, D.-H., Nam, C., Park, M.-C., Nam, S.-H. (2003). Determinants of emerging-market bond spreads: Cross-country evidence. Global Finance Journal, 14(3), 271–286.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minor, M.S. (1994). The demise of expropriation as an instrument of LDC policy, 1980-1992. Journal of International Business Studies, 25(1), 177–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moran, T.H. (1998). Managing International Political Risk. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nenova, T. (1999). The value of a corporate vote and private benefits: A cross-country analysis. Department of Economics, Harvard University, Unpublished Working Paper.

  • Neumayer, E., & Spess, L. (2005). Do bilateral investment treaties increase foreign direct investment to developing countries? World Development, 33(10), 1567–1585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nizalova, O.Y., & Murtazashvili, I. (2016). Exogenous treatment and endogenous factors: Vanishing of omitted variable bias on the interaction term. Journal of Econometric Methods, 5(1), 71–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Northrup, C.C., & Prange Turney, E.C. (2003). Encyclopedia of Tariffs and Trade in US History: The encyclopedia Vol. 3. Westport: Greenwood Publishing Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, N., & Qian, N. (2014). US Food aid and civi conflict. American Economic Review, 104(6), 1630–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oatley, T., & Yackee, J. (2004). American interests and IMF lending. International Politics, 41(3), 415–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olleta, A. (2007). The World Bank’s Influence on Water Privatization in Argentina: The Experience of the City of Buenos Aries. IELRC Working Paper 2007-02 International Environmental Law Research Centre.

  • Pepinsky, T.B. (2012). Do Currency Crisis Cause Capital Account Liberalization? International Studies Quarterly, 56(3), 544–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrova, M., & Bates, R. (2012). Evolution of risk and political regimes. Economics & Politics, 24(2), 200–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, C.M., & Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, C.M., & Rogoff, K.S. (2014). Recovery from financial crises: Evidence from 100 episodes. American Economic Review, 104(5), 50–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Remmer, K.L. (1991). The political impact of economic crisis in Latin America in the 1980s. American Political Science Review, 85(3), 777–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rudra, N. (2008). Globalization and the race to the bottom in developing countries: Who Really Gets Hurt?. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Salacuse, J.W., & Sullivan, N.P. (2005). Do BITs really work: An evaluation of bilateral investment treaties and their grand bargain. Harv. Int’l LJ, 46, 67–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandleris, G. (2008). Sovereign defaults: information, investment and credit. Journal of International Economics, 76(2), 267–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A., & Wolfenzon, D. (2002). Investor protection and equity markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 66(1), 3–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singer, M.M. (2010). Who says its the economy? Cross-national and cross-individual variation in the salience of economic performance. Comparative Political Studies, 44(3), 284–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staats, J.L., & Biglaiser, G. (2012). Foreign direct investment in latin america: The importance of judicial strength and rule of law. International Studies Quarterly, 56(1), 193–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R.W. (2011). Controlling institutions: International organizations and the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Terza, J.V., Basu, A., Rathouz, P.J. (2008). Two-stage residual inclusion estimation: addressing endogeneity in health econometric modeling. Journal of Health Economics, 27(3), 531–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thacker, S.C. (1999). The high politics of IMF lending. World Politics, 52(1), 38–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomz, M., & Wright, M.L.J. (2010). Sovereign theft: Theory and evidence about sovereign default and expropriation. In Hogan, W., & Sturzenegger, F. (Eds.) The natural resources trap: Private investment without public commitment (pp. 69–110). Cambridge: MIT Press.

  • UNCTAD. (1998). Bilateral Investment Treaties in the Mid-1990s. United Nations: Geneva.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD. (2008). World investment report. New York: United Nations Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vernon, R. (1998). In the Hurricane’s Eye: The Troubled Prospects of Multinational Enterprises. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wellhausen, R.L. (2015a). Bondholders vs. Direct Investors? Competing Responses to Expropriation. International Studies Quarterly, 59(4), 750–764.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wellhausen, R.L. (2015b). Investor–state Disputes When Can Governments Break Contracts? Journal of Conflict Resolution, 59(2), 239–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wells, L.T., & Ahmed, R. (2007). Making Foreign Investment Safe: Property Rights and National Sovereignty. London: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Werker, E., Ahmed, F.Z., Cohen, C. (2009). How is foreign aid spent? Evidence from a natural experiment. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(2), 225–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J.M. (1999). Quasi-likelihood methods for count data. In Handbook of applied econometrics, (Vol. 2 pp. 321–368). New York: Wiley Online Library.

  • Wooldridge, J.M. (2014). Control function methods in applied econometrics. The Journal of Human Resources, 50(2), 420–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wurgler, J. (2000). Financial markets and the allocation of capital. Journal of Financial Economics, 58(1), 187–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yackee, J.W. (2008). Conceptual difficulties in the empirical study of bilateral investment treaties. Brooklyn Journal of International Law, 33(2), 405–462.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zingales, L. (1994). The value of the voting right: A study of the Milan stock exchange experience. Review of financial Studies, 7(1), 125–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nathan M. Jensen.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 310 KB)

(CSV 2.08 MB)

(R 4.65 KB)

(RAR 5.79 MB)

(RAR 530 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Jensen, N.M., Johnston, N.P., Lee, Cy. et al. Crisis and contract breach: The domestic and international determinants of expropriation. Rev Int Organ 15, 869–898 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-019-09363-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-019-09363-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation