Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Et Tu, Brute? Wealth Inequality and the Political Economy of Authoritarian Replacement

  • Published:
Studies in Comparative International Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

What motivates elite factions to seek to replace an authoritarian incumbent? In this article, I provide a political economy theory of authoritarian replacement. I argue that high wealth inequality fosters authoritarian replacement, but that the effect is conditional on overall wealth being low. At low wealth, elite factions have an incentive to control the state to appropriate income. As wealth grows, elites shift their focus toward securing their wealth and thus prioritize finding credible commitments and stability within authoritarianism. I test these hypotheses using data from 1960 to 2008 and employ multistate survival analysis. A case study of Trujillo’s rise in the Dominican Republic illustrates the mechanisms of the theory. The evidence supports the main theoretical expectation that replacement is more likely when the level of wealth is low but wealth inequality is high.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. I am indeed aware that the most accurate conceptual concept would be “intra-elite” inequality, as the struggle for power is among elite groups, not the poor versus the rich. But I make the assumption that “intra-elite” and “class” inequality, while being theoretically different, closely mirror each other in practice. I develop on these arguments further in the theory section.

  2. In my tests, democracy and democratic breakdown are included to account for the full scope of transitions that countries can experience. This conforms with the multistate survival model used in the empirical section of this paper. Including all transitions reduces coefficient bias. However, no theoretical contribution is offered in this paper for democratization or democratic breakdown. This will be explained in more detail in the methods section.

  3. An updated version of the dataset to 2015 is available at Harvard Dataverse.

  4. I do not introduce a formal model explicitly; the formula below will be useful only as an analytical tool to describe how wealth grows in the long run.

  5. Note that, in the case of the Dominican Republic, lower levels of repression after 1905 were aided by the USA taking over the country’s customs that year and by the signing of the American-Dominican convention in 1907. A more peaceful environment was beneficial to both countries.

  6. A similar and related argument is that as the economy grows wealthier, elites find that alternatives to generate wealth emerge that do not require state capture.

  7. The results obtain if a simple multinomial logistic model is used. Tests are available from the author.

  8. The choice to use the multistate survival model is predicated on the fact that it can account for all possible transitions rather than focus on only one of the potential outcomes. As Metzger and Jones (2016) argue, not including all possible transitions in the analysis can lead to biased estimates. Using the multistate survival model reduces potential biases when analyzing relationships that are part of a broader set of potential outcomes.

  9. The multistate model is estimated using a discrete-time stratified Cox procedure. I provide a description of the particulars of the model and the dataset structure in the Appendix.

  10. Regime change in GWF includes reshuffling coups, which could be argued to not lead to a coalition change behind the dictator. I have included additional tests in the Appendix (see Tables A3 and A4) using data from the CHISOLS project (Mattes et al. 2016), which captures changes in the source of leader support in democracy and autocracy.

  11. The dataset can be found at https://stat.unido.org

  12. The economic elite is broadly defined as top centile of an economy.

  13. Data accessed in February 2022. It can be found at https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NE.GDI.FTOT.CD

  14. An in-depth description of the variable is included in Appendix A1, including the World Bank’s own detailed definition.

  15. I use the GDP measure to ensure that countries in the authoritarian replacement sample are by and large at the lower end of the GDP per capita distribution, and are thus not wealthy at the beginning of the measure.

  16. Our variable cannot capture all forms of wealth that elites may have, such as financial assets, stocks, and savings. Neither does it account for foreign ownership of assets. However, I contend that these omissions do not harm the validity of our measure. The level and growth of these assets tend to be highly correlated with the ones in the measure, and foreign ownership, while important, appears to have a small impact on our measure overall. I provide as evidence of our logic the correlations with Piketty’s private wealth data for a subsample of countries. These are all above 0.9 and are detailed below.

  17. These are the USA, Canada, China, Russia, the UK, Australia, Czech Republic, Japan, Mexico, South Africa, Netherlands, South Korea, Denmark, Germany, France, Greece, Italy, Spain, Norway, Finland, and Sweden. Within-correlation scores are stable across groups, with the exception of South Africa and, to a lesser extent, Greece. The correlation stays high if each or both countries are excluded from the test.

  18. The USA, Canada, Australia, Japan, Netherlands, South Korea, France, Germany, Italy, Spain, and Sweden. Within-correlation scores are stable across all groups.

  19. I do not include multiple interactions with square or cubic splines, which overly constrain the data.

  20. The results of the Cox proportional hazards model are presented in log-odds, not hazard ratios.

  21. The curve for all other regimes is a weighted average. No CIs are shown as statistical significance has been defined in Fig. 3a; survival curves are sufficient to show substantive significance.

  22. In fact, since the USA controlled the DR customs since 1905 and most of the government’s tax revenue came from tariffs, taxing firms to extract rents was barely possible. Hence, contracts, licenses, and concessions were the only way to extract rents profitably.

References

  • Acemoglu, Daron, Robinson, James A. Democratization or repression? Eur Econ Rev 2000;44(4):683–693.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, Daron, Robinson, James A. 2001. A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 938–963.

  • Acemoglu, Daron, Robinson, James A. 2006. Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge University Press.

  • Acosta, Alberto. Breve historia económica del Ecuador. Corporación Editora Nacional: Quito; 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  • Albertus, Michael. 2015. Autocracy and redistribution. Cambridge University Press.

  • Albertus, Michael, Menaldo, Victor. If you’re against them you’re with us: the effect of expropriation on autocratic survival. Comp Pol Stud 2012;45(8): 973–1003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albertus, Michael, Menaldo, Victor. Gaming democracy: elite dominance during transition and the prospects for redistribution. British Journal of Political Science 2014;44(3):575–603.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alvaredo, Facundo, Chancel, Lucas, Piketty, Thomas, Saez, Emmanuel, Zucman, Gabriel. 2017. World inequality report 2018. The World Inequality Lab. http://www.wir2018.wid.world.

  • Ansell, Ben, Samuels, David. Inequality and democratization: a contractarian approach. Comp Pol Stud 2010;43(12):1543–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansell, Ben, Samuels, David. 2014. Inequality and democratization. Cambridge University Press.

  • Boix, Carles. 2003. Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge University Press.

  • Boix, Carles, Miller, Michael, Rosato, Sebastian. A complete data set of political regimes, 1800–2007. Comp Pol Stud 2013;46(12):1523–1554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonilla, Heraclio. Guano y burguesía en el Perú. Instituto de Estudios Peruanos: Lima; 1984.

    Google Scholar 

  • Box-Steffensmeier, Janet, Jones, Bradford. 2004. Event history modeling: a guide for social scientists. Cambridge University Press.

  • Brownlee, Jason. 2007. Authoritarianism in an age of democratization. Cambridge University Press.

  • Bulmer-Thomas, Victor. 2003. The economic history of Latin America since independence. Cambridge University Press.

  • Cheibub, José Antonio, Gandhi, Jennifer, Vreeland, James Raymond. Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice 2010;143(1–2):67–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cotler, Julio. State and regime: comparative notes on the Southern Cone and the Enclave Societies. The new authoritarianism in Latin America. In: Collier, David and Cardozo, Fernando Henrique, editors. Princeton University Press; 1979. p. 255282.

  • Crassweller, Robert D. 1966. Trujillo: The life and times of a Caribbean dictator. Macmillan New York.

  • Evans, Peter B. 1995. Embedded autonomy: states and industrial transformation. Princeton University Press.

  • Gandhi, Jennifer. 2008. Political institutions under dictatorship. Cambridge University Press.

  • Geddes, Barbara. What do we know about democratization after twenty years? Annu Rev Polit Sci 1999;2(1):115–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geddes, Barbara, Wright, Joseph, Frantz, Erica. Autocratic breakdown and regime transitions: a new data set. Perspect Polit 2014;12(02):313–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gehlbach, Scott, Keefer, Philip. Investment without democracy: ruling-party institutionalization and credible commitment in autocracies. J Comp Econ 2011;39(2):123–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghura, Mr Dhaneshwar, Mercereau, Benoît. 2004. Political instability and growth: the Central African Republic. 4-80, International Monetary Fund.

  • Haggard, Stephan, Kaufman, Robert R. Inequality and regime change: democratic transitions and the stability of democratic rule. American Political Science Review 2012;106(03):495–516.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haggard, Stephan, Kaufman, Robert R. 2016. Dictators and democrats: masses, elites, and regime change. Princeton University Press.

  • Hall, Michael R. Sugar and power in the Dominican Republic. Eisenhower, Kennedy, and the Trujillos: Greenwood Press; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Houle, Christian. Inequality and democracy: why inequality harms consolidation but does not affect democratization. World Politics 2009;61(04):589–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houle, Christian. Why class inequality breeds coups but not civil wars. J Peace Res 2016;53(5):680–695.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karl, Terry L. 1997. The paradox of plenty: oil booms and petro-states. University of California Press.

  • Knutsen, Carl Henrik. Reinvestigating the reciprocal relationship between democracy and income inequality. Review of Economics & Institutions 2015;6:2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Little, Andrew T. Coordination, learning, and coups. J Conflict Resolut 2017;61(1):204–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magaloni, Beatriz. 2006. Voting for autocracy: hegemonic party survival and its demise in Mexico. Cambridge University Press.

  • Mattes, Michaela, Leeds, Brett Ashley, Matsumura, Naoko. Measuring change in source of leader support: the CHISOLS dataset. J Peace Res 2016;53 (2):259–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metzger, Shawna K., Jones, Benjamin T. Surviving phases: introducing multistate survival models. Polit Anal 2016;24(4):457–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, Roger B. The autocrat’s credibility problem and foundations of the constitutional state. American Political Science Review 2008;102(1):125–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donnell, Guillermo A, Schmitter, Philippe C. 1986. Transitions from authoritarian rule: Tentative conclusions about uncertain democracies. Johns Hopkins University Press.

  • Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the twenty-first century. Harvard University Press.

  • Przeworski, Adam. 1991. Democracy and the market: political and economic reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge University Press.

  • Przeworski, Adam. Democracy as an equilibrium. Public Choice 2005;123(3):253–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, Adam, Limongi, Fernando. Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives 1993;7(3):51–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, Adam, Alvarez, Michael, Cheibub, Jose, Limongi, Fernando. 2000. Democracy and development: political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950–1990. Cambridge University Press.

  • Putter, Hein, Fiocco, M., Geskus, R. B. Tutorial in biostatistics: competing risks and multi-state models. Stat Med 2007;26(11):2389–2430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, Michael. Does oil hinder democracy? World Politics 2001;53 (3):325–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, Naunihal. 2014. Seizing power: the strategic logic of military coups. JHU Press.

  • Slater, Dan. 2010. Ordering power: contentious politics and authoritarian leviathans in Southeast Asia. Cambridge University Press.

  • Slater, Dan, Wong, Joseph. The strength to concede: ruling parties and democratization in developmental Asia. Perspect Polit 2013;11(3):717–733.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Alastair. The perils of unearned income. The Journal of Politics 2008;70(3):780–793.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svolik, Milan W. Power sharing and leadership dynamics in authoritarian regimes. American Journal of Political Science 2009;53(2):477–494.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svolik, Milan W. 2012. The politics of authoritarian rule. Cambridge University Press.

  • Timoneda, Joan C. Institutions as signals: how dictators consolidate power in times of crisis. Comp Polit 2020;53(1):49–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turits, Richard Lee. 2003. Foundations of despotism: peasants, the Trujillo regime, and modernity in Dominican history. Stanford University Press.

  • Vanhanen, Tatu. 1997. Prospects of democracy: a study of 172 countries. Psychology Press.

  • Wright, Joseph. Do authoritarian institutions constrain? How legislatures affect economic growth and investment. American Journal of Political Science 2008;52(2):322–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, Joseph, Escriba-Folch, Abel. Authoritarian institutions and regime survival: transitions to democracy and subsequent autocracy. British Journal of Political Science 2012;42(02):283–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, Joseph, Bak, Daehee. Measuring autocratic regime stability. Research & Politics 2016;3:1.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Ernesto Calvo, Sebastián Vallejo Vera, Mark Lichbach, Pablo Beramendi, Erik Wibbels, Diego Romero, Jeremy Springman, Shawna Metzger, and participants at MPSA and APSA panels for their helpful comments and suggestions. I would also like to thank the editor and three anonymous reviewers, whose suggestions greatly improved the article.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joan C. Timoneda.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 2
Table 3

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Timoneda, J.C. Et Tu, Brute? Wealth Inequality and the Political Economy of Authoritarian Replacement. St Comp Int Dev 58, 557–583 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-022-09377-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12116-022-09377-6

Keywords

Navigation