Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-r6qrq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T09:46:04.332Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

6 - The Political Consequences of Internal Party Democracy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 October 2009

José María Maravall
Affiliation:
Professor of Sociology, Universidad Complutense de Madrid; Director, Centro de Estudios Avanzados en Ciencias Sociales (Instituto Juan March)
José María Maravall
Affiliation:
Juan March Institute, Madrid
Ignacio Sánchez-Cuenca
Affiliation:
Juan March Institute, Madrid
Get access

Summary

Introduction

My purpose is to explore whether democracy within the incumbent party can help citizens to monitor the government, that is, if the internal accountability of party leaders facilitates their external accountability as public office holders. On one hand, voters might reward parties in which internal monitoring provides information needed to control ruling politicians. On the other hand, internal partisan debates may carry too much noise for citizens and entail costs for the political capacity of the government. Voters might, in this case, reward disciplined parties and punish undisciplined ones; this would reinforce the position of leaders at the expense of critical activists. External electoral considerations would then be detrimental to the internal accountability within the party. I examine parliamentary democracies only. The reason is not that parties are different under presidentialism and parliamentarism, but rather that the relationship of the governing party with the executive is not the same.

Let us start with some clarifications on who's who. Think first of voters. Citizens elect for office that party whose promises are closer to their own political preferences, and they want the elected government to be democratically accountable and politically capable. Such a government would provide information about its actions and answer for them at election time. However, it would also need to be able to implement its promises, and this ability could be undermined by internal dissent and factionalism. Voters will face trade-offs if accountability were to hamper capacity, or vice versa.

Type
Chapter
Information
Controlling Governments
Voters, Institutions, and Accountability
, pp. 157 - 201
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abramowitz, Alan I. 1989. “Viability, Electability, and Candidate Choice in a Presidential Primary Election: A Test of Competing Models.” Journal of Politics 51 (4): 977–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Achen, Christopher H. 1992. “Social Psychology, Demographic Variables, and Linear Regression: Breaking the Iron Triangle in Voting Research.” Political Behavior 14 (3): 195–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aldrich, John. 1995. Why Parties?Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Stephen, E. Spear. 1988. “An Overlapping Generation Model of Electoral Competition.” Journal of Public Economics 37 (3): 359–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, James E. 1984. “Dealignment and the Dynamics of Partisanship in Britain.” In Russell, J. Dalton, Scott, C. Flanagan, Paul., A. Beck (eds.), Electoral Change in Advanced Industrial Societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Attlee, Clement. 1937. The Labour Party in Perspective. London: Odham.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, David. 1990. “Information Transmission in Debate.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (1): 124–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benn, Tony. 1992. The End of An Era. London: Hutchinson.Google Scholar
Bille, Lars. 2001. “Democratizing a Democratic Procedure: Myth or Reality? Candidate Selection in Western European Parties, 1960–1990.” Party Politics 7 (3): 363–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caillaud, Bernard, and Jean, Tirole. 2002. “Parties as Political Intermediaries.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1453–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cebrián, Juan Luis. 1989. “Reflexiones Electorales.” El País, 9 October.
Cheibub, José Antonio, and Adam Przeworski. 1999. “Democracy, Elections, and Accountability for Economic Outcomes.” In Przeworski, Adam, Stokes, Susan C., and Manin, Bernard (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cotta, Maurizio. 1999. “On the Relationship between Party and Government.” Occasional Papers 6/1999. Università degli Studi di Siena (published in Blondel, Jean and Cotta, Maurizio (eds.), The Nature of Party Government. London: Macmillan, 2000).Google Scholar
Cox, Gary. 1987. “Electoral Equilibria Under Alternative Voting Institutions.” American Journal of Political Science 31 (1): 82–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Gary. 1990. “Centripetal and Centrifugal Incentives in Electoral Systems.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (4): 903–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crossman, Richard. 1961. The New Statesman. 30 June.
Crossman, Richard. 1963. Foreword to William Bagehot, The English Constitution. London: Fontana.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert. 1970. After the Revolution?New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John, and Roger, G. Noll. 1978. “Uncertainty and the Formal Theory of Political Campaigns.” American Political Science Review 72 (2): 492–505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 2001. Special Interest Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Heath, Anthony, Jowell, Roger, and Curtice, John. 1994. Labour's Last Chance? The 1992 Election and Beyond. Aldershot: Dartmouth Publishing.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert. 1970. Exit, Voice, and Loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Holmes, Martin. 1985. The Labour Government, 1974–79. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Howell, David. 1976. British Social Democracy. London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Iversen, Torben. 1994a. “Political Leadership and Representation in West European Democracies: A Test of Three Models of Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 38 (1): 45–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iversen, Torben. 1994b. “The Logics of Electoral Politics: Spatial, Directional, and Mobilizational Effects.” Comparative Political Studies 27 (2): 155–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kato, Junko. 1998. “When the Party Breaks Up. Exit and Voice among Japanese Legislators.” American Political Science Review 92 (4): 857–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katz, Richard S., and Mair, Peter. 1995. “Changing Models of Party Organization and Party Democracy: The Emergence of the Cartel Party.” Party Politics 1 (1): 5–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Key, Vernon O. 1966. The Responsible Electorate. New York: Vintage Books.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiewiet, Roderick, and McCubbins, Mathew. 1991. The Logic of Delegation. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Lohmann, Suzanne. 1998. “An Information Rationale for the Power of Special Interests.” American Political Science Review 92 (4): 809–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mair, Peter. 1997. Party System Change. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Mair, Peter, and Ingrid, Biezen. 2001. “Party Membership in Twenty European Democracies.” Party Politics 7 (1): 5–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manin, Bernard, Adam Przeworski, and Susan C. Stokes. 1999. “Elections and Representation.” In Przeworski, Adam, Susan, C. Stokes, and Manin, Bernard (eds.), Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maravall, José María. 1991. “From Opposition to Government. The Politics and Policies of the PSOE.” In Maravall, José María. (eds.), Socialist Parties in Europe. Barcelona: ICPS.Google Scholar
Maravall, José María. 2007. “Accountability and the Survival of Governments.” In Boix, Carles and Stokes, Susan (eds.), Oxford Handbook of Comparative Politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
May, John D. 1973. “Opinion Structure of Political Parties: The Special Law of Curvilinear Disparity.” Political Studies 21 (2): 133–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKenzie, Robert. 1982. “Power in the Labour Party: The Issue of Intra-Party Democracy.” In Kavanagh, Dennis (ed.), The Politics of the Labour Party. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Michels, Robert. 1962. Political Parties. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Minkin, Lewis, and Patrick Seyd. 1977. “The British Labour Party.” In William, E. Patterson and Alastair, H. Thomas (eds.), Social Democratic Parties in Western Europe. London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Müller, Wolfgang. 2000. “Political Parties in Parliamentary Democracies: Making Delegation and Accountability Work.” European Journal of Political Research 37 (3): 309–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popkin, Samuel L. 1991. The Reasoning Voter. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Powell, G. Bingham, and Guy, D. Whitten. 1993. “A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context.” American Journal of Political Science 37 (2): 391–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ranney, Austin. 1981. “Candidate Selection.” In Butler, David, Penniman, Howard, and Ranney, Austin (eds.), Democracy at the Polls. Washington: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Richards, Andrew. 1997. The Life and Soul of the Party: Causes and Consequences of Organizational Change in the British Labour Party, 1979–1997. Estudio/Working Paper 1997/95. Madrid: Instituto Juan March de Estudios e Investigaciones.Google Scholar
Rosenstone, Steven. 1995. “Electoral Institutions and Democratic Choice.” Paper presented at workshop on “The Impact of Institutional Arrangements on Electoral Behavior.” European Consortium for Political Research, joint sessions of workshops. Bordeaux, 27 April–2 May.
Samuelson, Paul A. 1958. “An Exact Consumption–Loan Model of Interest with or without the Social Contrivance of Money.” Journal of Political Economy 66 (6): 467–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sartori, Giovanni. 1987. The Theory of Democracy Revisited. Chatham: Chatham House.Google Scholar
Scarrow, Susan. 1999. “Parties and the Expansion of Direct Democracy: Who Benefits?Party Politics 5 (3): 343–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seyd, Patrick, and Whiteley, Paul. 1992. Labour's Grass Roots. The Politics of Party Membership. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth, and Ronald Cohen. 1990. “Multiparty Competition, Entry, and Entry Deterrence in Spatial Models of Elections.” In Enelow, James and Hinich, Melvin (eds.), Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokes, Susan C. 1999. “Political Parties and Democracy.” Annual Review of Political Science 2 (1): 243–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokes, Susan C. 2001. Mandates and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stone, Walter J., and Alan, I. Abramowitz. 1984. Nomination Politics: Party Activists and Presidential Choice. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Str⊘m, Kaare. 1990. “A Behavioral Theory of Competitive Political Parties.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (2): 565–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Webb, Beatrice. Diaries. 19 May 1930. Archives Division, British Library of Political and Economic Science. London: London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
Webb, Paul. 2000. The Modern British Party System. London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Wildavsky, Aaron. 1965. “The Goldwater Phenomenon: Purists, Politicians, and the Two-Party System.” Review of Politics 27 (3): 386–413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williams, Philip. 1982. Hugh Gaitskell. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald. 1995. The Myth of Democratic Failure. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×