Skip to main content
Intended for healthcare professionals
Available access
Research article
First published online July 8, 2020

Leftist Insurgency in Democracies

Abstract

Leftist insurgency has been a major form of civil war since 1945. Existing research on revolution has linked leftist rebellions to authoritarianism or blocked democratization. This research overlooks the onset of leftist insurgencies in a number of democracies. This paper theorizes the roots of this distinctive form of civil war, arguing that democracy shapes how these insurgencies begin, acting as a double-edged sword that simultaneously blocks the emergence of a revolutionary coalition and triggers intra-left splits that breed radical splinters. Leftist revolts can thus emerge during “incorporation windows” that trigger disputes within a divided left over electoral co-optation. Empirically, the paper studies all cases of leftist insurgency in southern Asia since 1945, under both autocracy and democracy, as well as a set of non-onset cases. It offers a new direction for understanding varieties of revolutionary mobilization, highlighting ideology, intra-left debate, and the multi-faceted effects of democracy on conflict.

Introduction

In April 1971, revolutionary violence swept across much of Sri Lanka as the Maoist Janatha Vimukthi Peramuna (JVP) sought to seize power in a leftist uprising. Thousands of deaths later, the revolt was quashed. This war presents a puzzle: the United Front ruling government in 1971 had been supported by the JVP in the 1970 election, was ideologically socialist and moving policy to the left, and had not repressed or targeted the JVP until the revolt was about to break out. Indeed, the hotbeds of the JVP’s revolution were precisely those that had voted for the United Front less than a year prior.
The JVP’s rebellion challenges the expectations of important research like Huntington (1968) and Acemoglu and Robinson (2006): it was a leftist insurgency in a full-suffrage democracy under a center-left government, during a period of open political contestation and mobilization. The redistributive tilt of the ruling United Front (UF) government did not placate the JVP, which instead saw the UF as following a fruitless path to neutralized co-optation. Rather than democracy and political participation acting as a brake on revolutionary violence, violence surged precisely at a moment of mainstream leftist breakthrough.1
1971 Sri Lanka is not unique: in Colombia (1964), India (1967), Burma (1948), the Philippines (1946 and 1968), Nepal (1996), Peru (1982), Laos (1958–9), and Bangladesh (1972), among others (such as Sri Lanka again in 1987), leftist insurgencies have emerged in periods of electoral democracy. These movements left a huge toll in blood and dislocation, some lasted for decades, and many had profound political consequences for the societies in which they arose.
This paper first uses medium-N data from South and Southeast Asia to show that existing claims about the relationship between democracy and leftist rebellion are open to empirical question. Rather than such rebellions primarily occurring against right-wing authoritarian governments or in response to repression, we see a number of wars that erupt under relatively open, full-suffrage democratic competition.
The paper then uses the 1971 JVP revolt in Sri Lanka as a theory-building case to outline a new mechanism of revolutionary insurgency under democracy. When internally-divided leftist movements face “incorporation windows” that force a hard choice between co-optation into mainstream electoral politics or rebelling against the political system itself, radical splinters are likely to break off in opposition to mainstream co-optation. This fragmentation can emerge from international diffusion, prior state efforts at division, and contingent organizational strategies adopted by leftist leaders. When an incorporation window emerges, radical left factions in fragmented environments both fear being frozen out by the mainstream left and see an opportunity to push pro-left momentum toward a seizure of power. This helps explain why a number of leftist revolts have been launched against democratic socialist and center-left elected government: indeed, some of the most loathed foes of communist revolutionaries have not been right-wing land-owners or oligarchs, but instead center-left parliamentary socialists, whether in 1919 Germany (McAdams, 2017), late 1960s West Bengal, or 1980s Peru (Ron, 2001). Material class alignments can collapse in the face of byzantine ideological and coalitional rivalries.
Drawing on the methodological approach pioneered in Haggard and Kaufman (2012), the paper examines the cases of leftist insurgency onset under democracy in post-1945 southern Asia to compare competing theories, allowing an assessment of which mechanisms provide insight into the actors, sequence, and political context of leftist revolts. Several of the cases provide clear support for the existing claim in the literature that democracies trigger revolt when they block political participation by the left. But a cluster of leftist insurgencies under democracy in southern Asia instead occurred during moments of leftward tilts in the polity, driven by feuding between factions of divided leftist movements over whether to accept mainstream incorporation in moments of electoral opportunity. These revolts emerged from tensions within the left over the prospects and perils of electoral politics. The research design more briefly explores two cases in which leftist revolt did not break out in democratic periods in southern Asia, and points to related dynamics in Latin America.
Why should we study these cases? First, revolutionary revolts in democratic systems directly contribute to broader debates in political science around redistribution, democracy, and revolution, since these debates often hinge on implicit or explicit theories of when redistributive revolts begin. By examining the actual conditions under which we see such insurgencies, this article shows the importance of giving greater analytical importance to revolutionary forces, in a corrective to the top-down, regime- and elite-centric accounts that currently dominate. “The masses” or “the poor” are analytical categories of limited use: instead, in many cases we see deep intra-class divisions along ideological lines.
Second, democratization and political incorporation put enormous pressure on political movements that must grapple with the perceived advantages and dangers of electoralism; the strategic dilemmas faced by leftist movements have far broader echoes, including in ethnic and separatist movements (Cunningham, 2014; Horowitz, 1985; Snyder, 2000). The findings here contribute to our understanding of when and how democracy co-opts potential insurgents, triggers their revolt, or does both simultaneously.
Finally, in a world of increasing inequality and political instability, conflicts driven by actors seeking to fundamentally reshape the foundations of political systems may remain relevant. Kalyvas (2015) has argued that Islamist rebels are the ideological successors of the Marxist-Leninist challenge to the Western order of the Cold War. The challenge of spiraling inequality confronts countries in both the developed and developing world; though unlikely to take the specific forms I study here, it is conceivable that we will see other armed revolutionary movements emerge.

Democracy and Revolution: Claims and Gaps

Research on civil war has sidestepped leftist insurgency as a distinctive category of analysis. Many excellent case-based studies have been done of communist revolt, whether in Vietnam or Colombia, but leftist revolt has attracted little theoretical attention in recent years. While extensive work has gone into the specific roots of ethnic revolt, conflicts waged by Marxist-Leninist or Maoist armed groups are waged lumped into a broader category of center-seeking or “ideological” insurgencies (Sambanis, 2001).
Yet the political claims and coalitions of leftist insurgencies are quite different from those of many other rebels. Balcells and Kalyvas (2015) find that Marxist-Leninist rebels fought longer and bloodier wars than their contemporaries, while Wood and Thomas (2017) find that leftist groups are more likely to include female combatants. Wood (2001, 2000) shows that leftist revolts from below can have distinctive long-term effects on regime type. This category of revolt would benefit from closer study, as part of a broader process of disaggregating forms of civil wars and types of conflict onsets: as Sambanis (2001, p. 259) notes, “Not all civil wars are the same.”2
One important caveat, however, we can take from his literature involves scope conditions. Wealthy and well-institutionalized states rarely experience civil conflict. The scope condition here are countries that are structurally susceptible to civil war (Fearon and Laitin, 2003). This directs our attention to medium- and weak-capacity states as the domain of any kind of serious leftist insurgent revolt.

Revolution and the Left: Existing Accounts

The literature on revolution and regimes provides more usefully specific arguments. It can be divided into two strands. The first notes that democracies may experience leftist revolts, but that they do not succeed in overthrowing governments (Goodwin and Skocpol, 1989, p. 495). Huntington (1968, p. 275) for instance, argues, that successful great revolutions “do not occur in democratic political systems.” Goodwin (2001) writes that “the ballot box has been the coffin of revolutionaries.” This literature is focused primarily on revolutionary victory as the outcome of interest, and it is correct that leftist revolts only overthrew authoritarian regimes.
The second, more relevant, strand seeks to explain the onset of revolutionary violence in the first place. It argues that authoritarian regimes are the most likely breeding grounds of leftist revolution. The canonical work on revolution almost exclusively focused on cases of authoritarian or semi-authoritarian regimes (Paige, 1975; Scott, 1976; Skocpol, 1979; Wolf, 1969). In Skocpol’s (1982) classic survey of the literature, the word “democracy” only appears in references to the title of Moore (1966), and “election” and “electoral” are absent.
Ron (2001, p. 570) summarizes that there is a “conventional wisdom in revolutionary theory, which suggests that elections and partial democracy are powerful disincentives to armed struggle.” Democracy prevents violence from below: avoiding revolutionary upheaval is precisely the reason that elites may be willing to commit to redistribution through democracy (Acemoglu and Robinson, 2006, Boix, 2003). For Boix (2003, 2008), revolt is only even theoretically considered under either autocracy or suffrage-limited democracy (for instance, Boix 2003, pp. 34–35, 47–49). He argues that “the excluded majority may resort to violence whenever the expected gain of revolting is larger than the value of accepting an authoritarian regime” (Boix, 2008, p. 398).
Acemoglu and Robinson (2006) conceive of “democratization as a commitment to future pro-majority policies by elites in the face of a revolutionary threat” (p. 27), and the move to democracy curtails the existence of that revolutionary threat—highly unequal societies should see a redistributive shift through elections that satisfy these pressures from below. Elite-dominated authoritarian political systems will not only be where leftist insurgencies are most likely to succeed (as in the first strand discussed above), but where they should erupt in the first place. This leads to Hypothesis 1 below.
H1. Democracy Defangs Leftist Revolt.
Full-suffrage democracies should not experience leftist insurgency because democracy redistributes toward the masses and reduces incentives for revolutionary insurrection.
Yet the existence of leftist rebellions in full-suffrage democracies makes clear that H1, at minimum, faces a number of exceptions. Acemoglu and Robinson (2006, pp. 26–27) note that democracies may not redistribute sufficiently to stave off revolt, but do not study such cases: “in reality, it will not always be the case that democracy is sufficiently pro-majority that it avoids revolution. . . however, to limit the scope of our analysis, we normally restrict our attention to situations where the creation of democracy avoids revolution. Historically, this seems to have been typical, and it means that we do not delve deeply into theories of revolution.” Huntington’s (1968) classic work on revolution and political order similarly argues that “if a democracy acts in an ‘undemocratic’ manner by obstructing the expansion of political participation, it may well encourage revolution” (pp. 275–276).
This provides the intuition for Hypothesis 2 (H2): leftist revolt occurs in democracies when they block political participation from the left. In Huntington’s formulation, democracies that repress leftist movements and do not satisfy the demands of sizable political constituencies will drive them toward revolt. Recent research shows that many democracies are indeed biased toward elites in ways that make straightforwardly equating democracy with redistribution implausible (Albertus, 2015; Slater et al., 2014). Finkel and Gehlbach (2020) advance a related proposition, arguing that revolt follows reform when local state actors undermine reform efforts and citizens turn to violence because of unmet expectations. There is an ongoing debate about civil war onset and repression in democracies over whether “anocracies” and other regime types that mix aspects of democracy and autocracy are most prone to political violence (Hegre et al., 2001; Jones and Lupu, 2018; Vreeland, 2008); advocates of the claim that violence is most likely in hybrid/anocratic regimes make arguments that overlap with this hypothesis.
Hypothesis 2: Undemocratic Democracies.
Leftist insurgencies arise in full-suffrage democracies when redistribution does not occur and political participation is blocked.

Thunder from the Left: Ideology, Incorporation, and Splinters

Hypothesis 2 provides a crucial insight. Yet the 1971 JVP revolt in Sri Lanka that opened this paper suggests a puzzle. The JVP had worked to help elect the United Front government of the left (Alles, 1976, p. 68), which pledged substantial nationalization and land reform. 1970–71 was a moment of left-wing breakthrough in Sri Lankan politics. Yet instead of being accommodated by democracy, mollified by the leftward tilt of policy, or content with lawful political mobilization, the JVP began preparing for revolt within weeks of the UF’s election. From its founding in the late 1960s, the JVP believed that “power could not be captured from the capitalist rulers by the democratic method of holding elections” (Alles, 1976, p. 51).
The JVP’s rhetoric focused heavily on the “betrayal” (p. 26) of the revolution by the parliamentary left, and its arming was intended “to capture power from whatever government was in control at the time [right UNP or leftist SLFP]” (Alles, 1976, p. 67). The group’s threats of revolt “commenced from August 1970” (Alles, 1976, p. 58)—soon after the left had swept to electoral power in the May 27 elections. Indeed, as Alles notes, these threats occurred “in spite of the fact that the United Front Government did not in any way curb the activities of the movement at that stage” (Alles, 1976, p. 64).
The 1971 JVP case suggests a different logic than H2’s focus on repression: rebellions can instead emerge during “incorporation windows” when left movements are faced with a hard choice between electoral co-optation, on the one hand, and revolutionary violence, on the other. These windows are particularly contentious when multiple organized actors exist on the left without a single dominant party or leadership. Fragmented movements are more prone to splintering along lines of ideology, personality, and organizational rivalry.
Incorporation windows can include the introduction of electoral democracy at decolonization, visible increases in leftist parties’ popularity in mainstream electoral politics, and overtures to left forces by political elites attempting to build new coalitions. These political moments can be momentary or last for years; in either case, they are new periods of potential advance within, rather than against, the electoral system.
In some cases, these breakthroughs are the outcome of intentional efforts to increase leftist leverage within mainstream politics. But often they arrive as unexpected shocks that reshuffle the array of possible options facing a movement: for instance, ruling elites may reach out to the left to make up for the breakdown of their own ruling coalition, international pressures may create incentives for governments to create more or less space for leftist political forces, and the success of one left faction may have implications for the prospects of others even if they were not a cause of that faction’s success. To avoid some of the problems of operationalization that can plague related arguments (like those on political opportunity structures), I specifically look for periods of (1) democratization, (2) leftist party growth in vote share and/or recent or new movements by left parties toward meaningful electoral engagement, and (3) international pressures for democratization and specifically openness toward the left. For instance, countries with tight alignment with the United States in contested parts of the developing world (such as Pakistan) during the Cold War seemed more likely to limit incorporation windows than in less-aligned countries (such as India).
Incorporation windows help us understand the timing of revolts, but on their own they are insufficient to explain variation. The outcomes of an incorporation window hinge further on movement structure: whether or not there is a dominant party that can control the behavior of leftist factions and groups. When a dominant party or leadership controls the left, it can direct political engagement and mobilization toward managed co-optation (Krause, 2017; Pearlman, 2008/2009; Staniland, 2014). If the movement is cohesive but uninterested in incorporation, these windows will have no impact one way or another: revolutionary “organizational weapons” (Selznick, 1952) will either try to use them as opportunities for subversion or simply ignore electoral politics while continuing anti-regime mobilization. In neither case should an incorporation window distinctly trigger conflict: either it will open space for smooth incorporation, or do nothing.
Things are more complex when a leftist movement is divided among multiple organizations and factions that possess substantive collective action capacity (i.e., there is not a dominant party plus a tiny and irrelevant fringe). Sometimes open rivalries and splinters emerge only once incorporation becomes possible, but I hypothesize that the organizational roots of factionalization should often be visible even prior to an incorporation window.
What explains this variation in movement fragmentation? There is no single cause of leftist unity or fragmentation, but we can identify a set of plausible mechanisms that can help explain variation across contexts. First, the historical legacies of past mobilization can create enduringly fragmented movements based on different social and class bases, linked to distinct factions, or divided among rivalrous leaders. Initial processes of party-building and contingency can have long-lasting effects (Shefter, 1994); this is especially important when these structures emerged well prior to the contemporary political system experiencing an incorporation window.
Second, international diffusion and pressure can induce both cohesion and fragmentation. When international backers push for unity, movements can consolidate (sometimes under serious pressure). By contrast, when a broader international movement is divided—for instance, in the aftermath of the Sino-Soviet split (Lüthi, 2008)—this can drive new divisions within domestic movements as different factions align with different international patrons and inspirations.
Finally, state repression in the past can have important implications for the structure of movements in the present (Della Porta, 1995, Finkel, 2017). Preemptive destruction of radical splinters can truncate the ideological range of leftist movements. Both through words and deeds, the state can lay down “red lines” for acceptable and unacceptable political positions that limit just how ideologically divided the left can be. State power can enforce a certain degree of ideological homogeneity, though there is no guarantee in a democracy that such efforts will work.
It is important to be transparent that incorporation windows and movement fragmentation are not always independent of one another: sometimes splintering results from incorporation, or regimes open space for incorporation when they see radical splinters emerge and the possibility for dividing and ruling thus emerging. We need to be attentive to this possibility in examining specific cases. However, these variables are often distinct from one another, and there is sufficient possibility of analytical distance to make the framework in Table 1 useful in helping us systematically think about variation.
Table 1. Incorporation Window Theory of Leftist Revolt.
    Incorporation window?
    Yes No
Left structure? Cohesive Managed co-optation if movement pro-incorporation; no effect otherwise Riding two horses: efforts to engage in both electoral and extra-electoral politics simultaneously
Divided Division and revolt by radicals driven by escalating disagreement with pro-incorporation section of left No discernible change amidst rivalrous and fragmented movement
Table 1 outlines different combinations of leftist movement structure and incorporation windows. When an incorporation window appears and the left is dominated by a cohesive and disciplined political party interested in joining mainstream politics, the movement may be able to embrace the parliamentary path without violent splits or major internal ruptures. A classic case of leftist incorporation, despite violence being a plausible option, was the Italian Communist Party’s (PCI) “Salerno turn” in the waning days of World War II and its acceptance of a mainstream electoral role. When a dominant party is uninterested in entering electoral politics, the emergence of an incorporation window will not have any discernible effect, one way or another: the party will continue anti-system mobilization.
When a cohesive left movement does not face a clear choice about incorporation, it will likely try to balance a degree of electoral participation alongside continuing non-electoral mobilization; I refer to this as “riding two horses.” In these cases, the movement is not forced to choose: it can maintain a foot in the electoral arena while also pursuing strategies outside of the electoral arena that may not be compatible with pure electoralism. This may be an unstable equilibrium over the long run if there is a tension between the two approaches, but a diverse repertoire of political activity can allow a movement to keep different options alive rather than making a decisive choice. Fragmented leftist movements without an electoral incorporation window will be divided and uncoordinated, but there will be no clear trigger for a radical revolutionary turn by any faction.
I argue that the greatest likelihood of revolt is found when an ideologically diverse and organizationally fragmented leftist movement faces an incorporation window. On the one hand, the possibility of gaining serious influence without the uncertainty and violence of revolution is deeply attractive to reformists, especially in a moment when previous constraints and limitation may be falling away. On the other hand, radicals often view electoral democracy as fundamentally unsuited to meaningful redistributions of power and property. The parliamentary path, in this view, only promises betrayal, moderation, and sterile electoralism. This debate has broader echoes within other strands of political mobilization, such as political Islam and ethno-separatism, and the literature on “spoilers” and rebel fragmentation in civil conflict.3
Differing ideological positions create dramatically different expectations about the likely fruits of parliamentary engagement. This ideological tension can fuel fratricidal spirals of fragmentation as individuals and factions turn against one another in the face of an incorporation window. Incorporation windows are key, though of course not the only, triggers for such conflict: they create a blend of fear and opportunity among the radical components of a divided movement. Radicals fear being frozen out in the new electoral dispensation, but also perceive an opportunity to drive a clearly ascendant general leftist tide further toward genuine revolution.
As in the JVP case, such radical breakaways are often unable to capture the traditional urban working classes because of these classes’ ties to the electoral arena through patronage and parties. Rather than representing the poorest of the poor, radicals are often students, intellectuals, and even, in some cases, have an elite background; Wickham-Crowley (1992) has noted the prominence of sons of elites in Latin American leftist insurgencies. Their exclusion from the incorporated bastions of the center-left forces them into marginal peripheries to try to build peasant armies (Scott, 1978/1979; Skocpol, 1982).
The existing work most similar to this theory is Ron’s (2001) important study of the Sendero Luminoso in 1980s Peru. He argues that “political liberalization pushed Sendero toward revolutionary war, not toward political acquiescence” (p. 582) because “those that refused to accept parliamentary democracy. . . would find themselves placed beyond the pale by the state and the newly legalized mainstream left” (p. 583). This paper builds on Ron’s valuable insights to offer a developed and predictive theory of the conditions under which these revolts occur, and by pursuing a systematic cross-case research design. Crucially, it goes further by arguing that leftist insurgencies under democracy are driven by systematic causes that cast doubt on accepted conventional wisdoms about revolution and regimes.
These intuitions lead to H3, which focuses more on politics within the left than on blocked leftist participation:
Hypothesis 3: Incorporation and Division.
Leftist insurgencies in full-suffrage democracies are most likely when divided leftist movements face moments of choice between mainstream electoral participation and violent extra-parliamentary mobilization.
Leftist revolt will not occur through this pathway under several conditions summarized in Table 1. First, left movements that never face real incorporation possibilities will have little reason to splinter over this choice. This could be because a movement is so marginal or divided that it has no prospect of electoral success, or because the group is managing to balance parliamentary participation with extra-parliamentary mobilization (i.e., able to keep both options open rather than having to choose). Second, incorporation without violence is most likely when there is a dominant party interested in electoral co-optation, and less likely when it is divided or fragmented. The outcome of greatest interest here is the choice of rebellion: a systematic study of leftist tides across the full spectrum of Table 1 will have to await future research.

Research Design

Revolts of any sort are rare, and particular types of insurgency are even rarer. There are serious limits to what we can infer. This is not a “silver bullet” study: instead, the goal is to establish the plausibility of the core propositions and to reinvigorate systematic research on revolutions and revolutionary civil war. Nevertheless, there are ways to improve confidence in claims that can guide future work. This paper adopts a multi-layered research design in an effort to maximize the credibility of findings, while transparently identifying inferential challenges and cases in which my core hypothesis is not supported. Given the difficulties of studying political violence, adopting an ecumenical and mechanism-oriented methodological approach seems like a reasonable move (Kalyvas, 2019).
The case sample is made up of countries in South and Southeast Asia since 1945. This is a context that has experienced large-scale political violence, but with dramatic variation in the nature and timing of revolts. The first layer of the research design examines all of the leftist insurgencies that emerged in post-World War II South and Southeast Asia. It intentionally selects onset cases to explore how many occurred in periods of democracy versus those that emerged under authoritarianism. These are all relatively poor and highly unequal societies in which the “median voter” should push for substantial redistribution under democracy. The Supplemental Appendix provides a detailed justification of the coding of the timing of rebellion onset and regime type, as well as far more extensive sourcing for the cases and greater discussion of relevant alternative explanations.
The next, more intensive, set of case comparisons examines the leftist insurgencies that did occur in democratic periods. It relies on “causal process observations” (Brady & Collier, 2010) within each case of leftist insurgency onset within a democracy. It compares H2 and H3 to see which best accounts for the timing and process of leftist insurgency, excluding the 1971 Sri Lanka revolt because of its use as a theory-building case for H3. This approach builds on the influential design of Haggard and Kaufman (2012, p. 4), who argue that “Selecting on the dependent variable is a central feature of this approach, which is designed to test a particular theory and thus rests on identification of the causal mechanism.” Examining each case to see which aligns most closely with the two specified mechanisms, or whether there is little support for either, then allows an assessment of the existence and relative frequency of contending mechanisms (Brady and Collier, 2010; George and Bennett, 2005).
Finally, the paper briefly examines 1947–54 Pakistan and 1949–65 Indonesia, in which insurgency did not emerge during periods of democracy. While the bulk of the empirical work focuses on the comparisons and causal process observations above, identifying non-onset cases lays the basis for more systematic future testing across contexts.

Leftist Revolts in Southern Asia

I identify 18 onsets of leftist insurgencies in post-1945 South Asia, shown in Table 2. This does not include groups that may have had Marxist leanings, like the Liberation Tigers of Tamil Eelam, but that were not formally communist organizations (cf. Kalyvas and Balcells, 2010; Wood and Thomas, 2017), as well as tiny groups that were never able to generate any real violence. I code leftist groups as those that explicitly articulate their goals in terms of Marxist-Leninist and/or Maoist theory, aiming to seize the state and engage in systematic transformation based on class categories. I identify whether the group launched its insurgency in a year of democracy or autocracy. The Appendix engages in detail with coding decisions and their implications.
Table 2. Leftist Revolts in post-1945 South and Southeast Asia.
Armed group Country Onset year Regime type Eventual outcome
Communist Party of Thailand (CPT) Thailand 1965 Authoritarian Govt. victory
Naxalites India 1967 Democracy Ongoing
Communist Party of India (CPI) India 1948 Democracy Govt. victory
Janatha Vimukthi Peramuna (JVP) Sri Lanka 1971 Democracy Govt. victory
JVP Sri Lanka 1987 Democracy Govt. victory
Communist Party of Nepal-Maoist (CPN-M) Nepal 1996 Democracy Neg. settlement
Communist Party of Burma (CPB) Burma 1948 Democracy Govt. victory
CPB-Red Flag Burma 1946 Authoritarian/Colonial Govt. victory
Peoples’ Volunteer Organisation Burma 1948 Democracy Govt. victory
Hukbalahap Philippines 1946 Democracy Govt. victory
New People’s Army (NPA) Philippines 1968 Democracy Ongoing
Pathet Lao Laos 1959 Democracy Rebel victory
Viet Minh French Indochina 1946 Authoritarian/Colonial Neg. settlement/Rebel victory
Viet Cong South Vietnam 1955 Authoritarian Rebel/N. Vietnamese victory
Khmer Rouge Cambodia 1967 Authoritarian Rebel victory
Malayan Communist Party (MCP) Malaya 1948 Authoritarian/Colonial Govt. victory
Jatiya Samajtantrik Dal (JSD) Bangladesh 1974 Democracy Govt. victory
Purba Bangla Sarbohara Party (PBSP) Bangladesh 1972 Democracy Govt. victory
Of these 18 onsets, I assess that 12 occurred in a democracy-spell. The evidence suggests that H1—the strong version of the claim that leftist insurgency is a straightforward product of authoritarian regimes—is not sustainable, especially after de-colonization. Whatever the precise balance of onset in democracy vs. autocracy, a substantial number of the leftist insurgencies occur under democracy. Table 2 also supports the claim in one strand of the literature that leftists only win against authoritarian regimes—by the end of the rebel victories in the dataset, they all faced authoritarian governments. Clearly, however, onset is not at all restricted to autocracies.
We can also consider how this record relates to the distribution of autocracy and democracy across the 15 countries I consider as part of southern Asia in the post-colonial period. For a rough but valuable sense of how common autocracy has been relative to democracy in this sample, I examine the data of Geddes et al. (2014), Svolik (2012), and Boix et al. (2013). They are consistent: all have roughly 65% to 70% of country-years as falling under some kind of autocracy and the reminder under democracy (see Appendix). Removing communist dictatorships, on the assumption that they are unlikely to be targeted by leftist insurgencies, does not change this pattern. Despite hugely important caveats, it is worth noting that the onset of leftist insurgency in democracies is higher than we would expect based on the simple distribution of country-years by regime type. Even more strikingly, in post-colonial independent countries, there were 15 leftist insurgencies (the MCP, CPB-Red Flag, and Viet Minh rebelled under colonial rule), of which as many as 12 (80%)—depending on coding decisions discussed in the Appendix—broke out under democracy, despite democracy accounting for only approximately 35% of non-communist-dictatorship years.

Leftist Revolts in Democracies in Southern Asia: Comparing Mechanisms

This section explores how H2 and H3 compare in explaining the onset under democracy cases. Both hypotheses are about processes and sequences. We can examine these sequences to see which mechanism—if any—matches the empirical record. To assess H2, I examine whether the insurgency was (1) preceded by a sustained program of repression against the left by the state that (2) “blocked” (a la Huntington, 1968) leftist participation and thus policy shifts toward redistribution. To assess H3, I measure (1) whether the revolt was preceded by/accompanied by intra-left splits over democratic incorporation, (2) the left-right orientation of the government against which the revolt was launched, and (3) whether there had been moments of democratization or leftist electoral breakthrough before or around the onset of the revolt.
This research designs selects on the dependent variable to explore the causal mechanism leading to onset, conditional on onset having occurred. There are clear limits to this approach (King et al., 1994), since there may be similar cases that did not turn to rebellion. All claims in the paper need to be appropriately caveated. However, as George and Bennett (2005), Brady and Collier (2010), and Mahoney (2010) argue, this approach can be valuable in weighing theories against one another by examining the process through which political phenomena unfolded. It allows us to compare how theories perform in explaining the timing, actors, and composition of revolts. Later in the paper, I briefly examine cases in which there was no leftist revolt during a period of democracy, to lay the basis for systematic future research.
Table 3 summarizes the 12 cases of leftist rebellion onset in periods of democracy and assesses whether each case is better explained by H2 or H3 (or neither). I find four cases that clearly support H2. I label these “State repression” cases. I identify seven cases that align reasonably closely with the incorporation windows argument of H3. However, one of the cases (1971 Sri Lanka) was a theory-building case, so I disregard it in this analysis. These emerged in periods in which the left was at least partially incorporated into mainstream politics, but radical splinters disagreed about the wisdom and viability of electoral contestation and chose revolt. This turn to violence occurred at moments of independence, democratization, and/or leftist electoral assertion in which the left’s eventual place in politics was wide open. Rather than a reaction to anti-democratic repression, these were ambitious revolts waged in large part against an ascendant, ruling center-left. The 1968–9 Philippines case provides partial support for both mechanisms.
Table 3. Leftist Insurgency Onsets in Democracy Periods.
  Mechanism Key dynamics
Huks, 1946 State repression Landlord-dominated government represses rural peasant organizations and leftist politicians
CPP-NPA, 1968-69 Both state repression and left incorporation Maoist radicals revolt against illiberal but democratic government while clashing with other communists
Naxalites, 1967 Left incorporation Maoist radicals revolt against newly-elected, leftist-dominated state government
CPB, 1948 Left incorporation Communist party revolts against Socialist-dominated center-left government
PVO-Whites, 1948 Left incorporation Leftist militia faction revolts against Socialist-dominated center-left government
CPI, 1948 Left incorporation Communist party revolts against center-left post-colonial government
JVP I, 1971 [theory-building case] Left incorporation Radical party revolts against center-left socialist government
JVP II, 1987 State repression Center-right government represses JVP on pretext; blocked party turns to violence
CPN-M, 1996 Left incorporation Communist faction turns against post-democratization governments, including elected communists
Jatiya Samajtantrik Dal (JSD), 1974 State repression Electoral leftists turn against state repression and slide to authoritarianism in 1974
Puro Banglar Sarbohara Party (PBSP), 1972 Left incorporation Radical leftists preemptively attack post-secession leftist government during clearly democritc period
Pathet Lao, 1959 State repression Right-dominated government attacks armed Communist party
This is a small set of cases and we can draw only very caveated inferences. However, it appears that there are two distinct pathways to leftist insurgency in democracies. One, found in the existing conventional wisdom, is driven by the (usually rightist) state repressing the left and thus spurring revolt driven by blocked political participation (H2). The other pathway is driven by dynamics within the left itself, with spiraling debates over democratic incorporation that turned violent (H3). Leftist insurgency is characterized by “equifinality” (George and Bennett, 2005)—multiple causal mechanisms can drive the onset of revolt. In the Appendix, I also explore other ways of categorizing these cases to see whether we can find other useful patterns to guide future research on the dynamics of redistributive revolt: for instance, I find suggestive evidence that Cold War alignment and transnational ideological diffusion affected incorporation windows and ideological heterogeneity.

Assessing H2: Does Leftist Revolt Follow Rightist Repression?

There are four clear cases that support H2. In all, governments preemptively targeted left movements prior to the onset of the insurgency. In two cases, this repression emerged in large part due to Cold War pressures (1946 Philippines, 1959 Laos); in the other two (1987 Sri Lanka, 1974 Bangladesh), democratically elected leaders began repressing their rivals as part of a bid to consolidate and personalize power.
In the 1946 Philippines, leftist peasant guerrillas and peasant organizations who had fought the Japanese during World War II were aggressively targeted by a landlord-dominated government. A rebellion emerged in response, tying together localized peasant groupings with parts of the Communist Party of the Philippines (KPK) (Staniland, 2014). A genuine incorporation window did not exist, because of the class dynamics within the Philippines and emerging Cold War worries about the left. The evidence is unambiguous that a right-leaning government preemptively targeted the left and triggered the revolt (Kerkvliet, 1977, pp. 143–151; Slater, 2010, pp. 96–102).
Laos 1959, Bangladesh 1974, and Sri Lanka 1987 are somewhat trickier cases: some datasets code 1987 Sri Lanka and 1974 Bangladesh as autocracies, while the Pathet Lao insurgency in Laos was the continuation of the leftist component of an earlier revolt (the Lao Issara) rather than the initial turn to violence. However, these are precisely the ambiguous cases in which we would expect to see H2 operate, with democratic processes breaking down amidst growing repression.
In 1983 Sri Lanka, the center-right UNP government banned the JVP (which had returned to mainstream politics in the late 1970s) after the anti-Tamil riots of July 1983 (Gunaratna, 1990, pp. 187–188). Though the government claimed that the JVP had a key role in the rioting (Gunaratna, 1990, pp. 187–190), there was no evidence of this—“the government was unable to come up with any convincing proof that the JVP was in any way responsible for instigating the riots” (Chandraprema, 1991, p. 60), which instead were closely linked to thugs of the ruling party. The JVP was blocked, despite its genuine interest in electoral participation; Chandraprema argues that “Between 1977 and 1983 the JVP did everything possible to make its electoral projections a success” (Chandraprema, 1991, p. 51). The group was forced underground, and began preparing for the revolt it eventually launched in 1987.
Laos had experienced a broad-based, but fragmented, rebellion against the French in 1946 in the Lao Issara government. This movement largely disintegrated in 1949. However, the Communist component of the Lao Issara continued to fight, establishing the Pathet Lao in 1950. After the 1954 Geneva Accords, the Pathet Lao’s political party wing, the Lao Patriotic Front (LPF) agreed to join a national unity coalition government (Stuart-Fox, 1997, p. 96). Much of the Pathet Lao demobilized, but some elite units were moved into Vietnam as insurance (Stuart-Fox, 1997, pp. 99–100). A “remarkably free and fair” (Stuart-Fox, 1997, p. 102) election in May 1958 brought the LPF substantial electoral power, though not into the government. However, right-wing discontent, Thai encouragement, and, especially, American financial pressure led to a rightist tilt within the government that “stepped up its repression of the LPF” (Stuart-Fox, 1997, p. 107) over the course of 1958 and 1959. The Pathet Lao had not fully demobilized, and it decided to throw these forces back into the fight while expanding its insurgent mobilization in areas of strength (Stuart-Fox, 1997, pp. 103–109), leading to war onset in 1959.
Finally, Bangladesh was born in war and secession from Pakistan in 1971. The leader of the Bengali movement was the leftist nationalist Sheikh Mujibur Rahman, who won Bangladesh’s post-independence 1973 election. Two major groups eventually took to war against the Mujib government—the JSD and PBSP. The PBSP, discussed below, shows little support for H2—it had been ultra-radical since the late 1960s and viewed parliamentary democracy as a sham. But the JSD is a different story. It emerged as a splinter from the ruling Awami League in October 1972, arguing that the AL was insufficiently radical. Unlike the PBSP, however, it was open to trying electoral politics in 1973, and became an opposition party that was comparatively more moderate than other ultra-left forces (Jahan, 1974, pp. 127–128; Mohaiemen, 2006, p. 301; Moten, 1980, pp. 72–81).
Mujib had created a paramilitary force, the Jatiya Rakkhi Bahini (JRB), that was deployed, arbitrarily and brutally, against the Awami League’s rivals—including the JSD. As Mujib moved toward a greater autocratization of Bangladesh, the JSD decided to go underground for self-defense in 1974: “It was the rise of the Bahinis that pushed JSD and others to also start arming themselves” (Mohaiemen, 2006, p. 301), founding an armed wing (the Biplobi Gonobahini) and aiming to overthrow Mujib (Masoom, 2000, pp. 39–40; Maniruzzaman, 1980, p. 184; Riaz, 2016, p. 54). This is clearly a case of state repression blocking democratic participation by leftist forces, contributing to a turn to insurgency. The JSD revolt—unlike its near-simultaneous contemporary, the PBSP—works for H2 better than H3.

Assessing H3: Incorporation Windows, Splintering, and the Turn to War

I now turn to the cases that support H3, which argues leftist insurgency is most likely when left movements face divisive choices about whether to embrace electoral co-optation. The four cases above that provide support to H3 and the first JVP revolt in 1971 (set aside as a theory-building case) leave us with seven cases to examine. I find that six of them provide robust support for H3, while one (the 1968–69 NPA revolt in the Philippines) provides only partial support. Ideology does important work in explaining why these specific rebels, but not their contemporaries in the broader left, thought that democracy could not deliver meaningful policy change, even in political systems in which the left held power or was advancing through the electoral system.

India: Revolutionary Road versus Parliamentary Path, 1948 and 1967

India has seen two leftist insurgencies—the Communist Party of India (CPI) first in 1948 and then the “Naxalites” in 1967. The political question that triggered both was the choice of whether to embrace incorporation into mainstream electoral politics. The CPI revolt of 1948 occurred just after independence, when the center-left Indian National Congress (INC) was consolidating its control over India. While the INC was ideologically heterogenous, including a powerful business-friendly faction (Chibber, 2003), its overall political orientation was center-left, including a prominent openly socialist bloc; it was certainly more democratic and left-leaning than the Raj that preceded it.
The CPI revolt occurred in part as a reaction to the prospect of the Left becoming domesticated within electoral democracy. The CPI feared being “caught in a political impasse that was threatening to marginalize them in the twilight years of decolonization” (Bandyopadhyay, 2008, p. 3). Its critiques of the INC (the so-called “Ranadive Line”) centered on its alleged obedience to the Anglo-American imperial order and the need to entirely overthrow the political status quo in India (Kennedy and Purushotham, 2012, pp. 836–837). The prospect of communist revolution across Asia encouraged the leadership of the CPI to increase their estimates of the odds of success. There was also an important local aspect to the CPI conflict, including anti-landlord mobilization predating independence in Hyderabad. But the leadership’s choice for war is consistent with seeking to take advantage of a window of opportunity before the consolidation of a hegemonic center-left regime that would permanently hold revolution at bay. The failure of the insurrection led the CPI to return to the parliamentary fold by 1951–52.
The second leftist rebellion in India began in 1967 West Bengal. If the 1948 revolt pitted the CPI against the specter of INC-dominated parliamentary hegemony, the 1967 revolt instead pitted one of the CPI’s splinters, the CPI-Marxist (CPM), and other leftist Bengali parties now in power in West Bengal against violent ultra-radical Maoists who saw the establishment left as selling out. The context was of Congress’ collapse in West Bengal and a leftist alliance (the United Front) forming the first non-Congress government of the state (Kohli, 1990). 1967 was a breakthrough moment for left-wing electoralism.
But alongside this electoral surge was a deepening ideological cleavage in West Bengal. While the CPI and CPM had split in the early 1960s, both remained intra-systemic mainstream electoral players. However, dissidents seethed within the CPM as the 1960s wore on. As the CPM looked to consolidate its electoral gains in West Bengal by entering power in the winning coalition, CPM dissidents on the left sparked violence in rural areas in 1967. The CPM’s remarkable success “brought intra-CPI (Marxist) conflict to a head” (Kennedy and Purushotham, 2012, p. 845). Franda notes that this was an unexpected shock—“the Left faction was caught off guard, and party factionalism immediately resurfaced” with “serious disagreement among the Communists, particularly within the CPM, about the wisdom of joining a coalition government” (1971, p. 150).
A group of anti-electoral radicals had been carving out space in northern Bengal since 1965 (Franda, 1971, p. 157), planning a major land agitation on the assumption that the incumbent Congress government would win in 1967. We see international influences on splintering clearly here: the inspiration of the Cultural Revolution in China contributed to intra-left rivalry, with many on the electoral left instead viewing the less revisionist USSR with greater favor. When the CPM instead moved toward incorporation, a “a great deal of tension developed” (Franda, 1971, p. 157). The resulting ultra-leftist land agitation, which soon turned violent and spiraled into war, was intended as a challenge to the mainstream electoral left:
“The first insurgent activity was reported in Naxalbari on the same day in March 1967 that the United Front was sworn into office. The timing was motivated by the Maoist faction’s desire to distinguish itself from the mainstream CPI (Marxist) and demonstrates the relative autonomy of insurgent actions from micro-level grievances” (Kennedy and Purushotham, 2012, p. 846)
Unsure how to respond, the United Front mixed repression with complacency (Kohli, 1990, p. 279), triggering insurgency that moved into the heart of urban Calcutta. The parliamentary left was one of the key targets of this “Naxalite” movement: the radicals “increasingly denounced the [ruling leftist] United Front” (Franda, 1971, p. 162) and attacked their cadres. Kohli argues that the Naxals were “an alienated militant minority whose members had recently renewed their sense of political efficacy versus a fragmented state that, in spite of its strong leftist orientation, stood de-legitimized in the eyes of the militants” (Kohli, 1990, p. 280). The CPM-Marxist-Leninist that emerged as the organizational vehicle of the Naxal insurgency explicitly argued that the left must “reject the hoax of parliamentarism” and instead pursue “immediate revolution” (quoted in Franda, 1971, p. 173).
The West Bengal revolt was subdued in 1972 through brute force repression, but its successors continue to operate in substantial areas of interior India, now in the form of the CPI-Maoist.4 Both Indian cases show strong support for the mechanism identified in H3—it was intra-left competition over democratic participation in a period of broadly left-wing advance that drove splits and violence, not state repression or a simple clash of wealthy against the masses.

Burma: Decolonization and Leftist Revolt, 1948–49

Like India, Burma emerged from the wreckage of the Raj with ethno-religious and left-right cleavages, amidst poverty and inequality. Unlike India, Burma would soon experience large-scale insurgency. Communist revolt had already begun under colonial rule in 1946, when a tiny splinter group of the Communist Party of Burma (CPB)—Thakin Soe’s CPB-Red Flag (Lintner, 1990, p. 10)—took up the gun. The breakaway Red Flag faction argued for the CPB “to give up its collaboration with the AFPFL and instead concentrate on leading and organizing a revolutionary uprising of the working class” (Smith, 1999, p. 68). Like the MCP and Viet Minh revolts, this insurgency emerged in the dying days of authoritarian empire.
However, the main leftist revolts came later, launched by the larger CPB-White Flag and parts of the People’s Volunteer Organisation (PVO) in 1948. The CPB’s turn to war by March 1948 (Callahan, 2003, p. 114; Lintner, 1990, pp. 11–14) was caused by its rivalry with and then split from the Aung San’s Socialist Party, which dominated the AFPFL coalition that succeeded the Raj. The CPB was de facto expelled from the AFPFL in November 1946 and “from this point on the Socialist Party nominees. . . dominated the AFPFL and held virtually all the key positions in the first post-independence government” (Smith, 1991, p. 69). The CPB saw itself being sidelined by the Socialists, who intended to lead a parliamentary democracy.
Independence thus promised both democracy and marginalization for the CPB at the hands of the center-left. The CPB’s decision for insurgency was intended to avoid this fate, which it believed would hold Burma into perpetual neo-colonialism and elite dominance: “a bitter row developed over the terms and true definition of Burma’s independence” (Smith, 1999, p. 102). The party was “outmaneuvered by Aung San and the Socialist Party in 1946” (Silverstein, 1990, p. 116), and by early 1948 the CPB now chose to pursue insurrection to “uproot the ‘disease of reformism’” (Smith, 1999, p. 105) that they believed the AFPFL was suffering from. Burma in 1948 was born as a democracy, and its policies were shifting left fast in the wake of decolonization. However, this redistributive tilt was inadequate for the CPB, which instead took up arms against a ruling socialist party.
Another revolt from the left broke out in 1948, by the “White Band” faction of the People’s Volunteer Organisation (PVO). The PVO had been set up by Aung San as “a veterans organization affiliated with the legal AFPFL” (Callahan, 2003, p. 121), but their already-tenuous cohesion disappeared after his assassination in the summer of 1947. The White Band faction of the PVO, with roughly 60% of the organization’s fighting strength, took to arms in July 1948 (Lintner, 1999, p. 7), frustrated by the government’s unwillingness to make peace with the CPB and form a leftist unity government (Smith, 1999, p. 108). This was a much more inchoate revolt than the CPB, reflecting a deeply divided and disorganized Burmese left (Smith, 1999, pp. 133–134). It fizzled out by the early 1950s; nevertheless, it played a major role in the early days of Burma’s civil wars as another disenchanted leftist armed group dismayed with the country’s drift into parliamentary democracy.

Bangladesh: The PBSP’s Turn Against Mujib, 1972–73

As we saw above, in 1974 the JSD took to arms through Huntington’s “blocked democracy” mechanism (H2). But there was an ongoing leftist revolt launched before Mujib’s turn toward autocracy that instead supports H3. 1972–73 Bangladesh was a chaotic political environment in which ultra-leftists watched with suspicion as Mujib and his Awami League rhetorically embraced both parliamentary democracy and India. The left was fractured, despite Mujib’s overall dominance: it had been riven by deep rivalries for years, and these tensions spilled out into fuller view after independence. The PBSP was a preexisting radical group was led by Siraj Sikdar. He had begun organizing what became the PBSP in 1967 as the Mao Thought Research Centre, which then became the East Bengal Workers Movement, and in 1971 was renamed the PBSP (Amin, 1986, pp. 760–763; Amin, 1985, pp. 354–356; Maniruzzaman, 1980, pp. 46–47). The group had a dim view of electoral democracy: even “On liberation day, Sharbahara members were already passing out leaflets calling this a “false freedom” and preparing for the coming armed struggle against the new government” (Mohaiemen, 2006, p. 300).
For Sikdar, there was an “unfinished revolution” to complete (Maniruzzaman, 1980, p. 171; Maniruzzaman, 1975, p. 900). Unlike the JSD in its early phase, the PSBP adopted from the very beginning a strategy of violence: “They had always argued that participating in elections was a sham; only Mao’s ‘barrel of a gun’ thesis would bring about ‘Marxism-Leninism-Maoism” (Mohaiemen, 2006, p. 301). Though Mujib was far to the left of the previous Pakistani military governments that had ruled East Pakistan, the group identified revolutionary contradictions in Bangladesh as early as its January 1972 National Congress. It pursued violence even during the adoption of constitutional democracy and the elections of 1973. The PBSP, unlike the JSD, was driven by a deep ideological distrust of and contempt for democracy, leading it to clash with a leftist elected government.

Nepal’s Post-Cold War Maoist Revolt

The final case that provides support for H3 is in many respects the oddest. Rather than emerging in the crucible of Cold War rivalry, the Communist Party of Nepal-Maoist’s turn to violence came in the mid-1990s, following Nepal’s democratization in 1990–1. Nepal had long had a radical left, small factions of which had engaged in isolated localized violence in past decades against the repressive, narrowly exclusionary monarchy. Yet it was under democracy that we see the most centralized and national leftist insurgency emerge.
The Nepalese left after democratization was deeply factionalized, with some groups, especially the CPN-Unified Marxist-Leninist (CPN-UML), embracing mainstream electoral politics (Hutt, 2004). Others, such as the CPN-Unity Centre, viewed the new political situation with deep skepticism. Among the latter group, fissures existed about whether to push for gains within the system, or to quickly attempt to overthrow it.
The emerging hard-liners within the CPN-Unity Centre “had little faith in the Constitution, in Parliament, in pluralism, and in what they dismissed as ‘bourgeoisie freedoms.’ They were merely waiting for the right time to launch an armed rebellion” (Jha, 2015, p. 18). Baburam Bhatturai, for instance, argued that revolutionary change “could not happen by playing according to the ‘democratic rules’ framed by the classes whom the Marxists sought to displace” (Jha, 2015, pp. 23–24). As Adhikari argues, “To the communists in the Unity Centre, those early years of democracy confirmed that parliamentary democracy was a sham: they believed it could never bring about the necessary transformation of Nepali society, making it necessary to wage war against the state and seize state power” (Adhikari, 2014, p. 15).
The Nepalese political system was corrupt and land reform largely stalled (per Albertus, 2015), and the nascent revolt found its most eager foot soldiers in marginalized rural communities. Yet the system remained a full-suffrage democracy and the leadership of the CPN-Maoist that chose war—while not elite—tended to be within (though on the lower end of) Nepal’s educated, privileged class (Adhikari, 2014, p. 6). This is not a case of democrats disillusioned by blocked democratic involvement, but instead one of committed, educated ideologues who believed that electoral politics could never deliver social change.
The CPN-Maoist was founded in 1994 after breaking with Unity Centre for being insufficiently radical: “The fissures culminated in the final 1994 split, which the Maoists described as a deliberate effort to purge their ranks of those who questioned the necessity of violence” (Thurber, 2015, p. 155). The CPN-M began arming for war even during a period in which the leftist CPN-UML was leading the national government in 1994–1995; it then launched its main offensives in early 1996. Nepal was certainly poor and unequal in the 1990s, but it was also a full-suffrage democracy moving away from repressive monarchy. This onset provides greater support for H3 than H2.

Support for both Mechanisms: The CPP/NPA Chooses War, 1968–69

The final case provides support to both H2 and H3: the CPP/NPA insurgency emerged in the late 1960s Philippines in a context of both blocked redistribution under democracy and visceral intra-left rifts over parliamentary politics. The Communist Party of the Philippines (CPP) was formed as an avowedly revolutionary party in late 1968. Its founding by Jose Maria Sison was a repudiation of the existing PKP, which had failed during its involvement in the Huk insurgency in the 1940s/early 1950s before returning to being mostly non-violent afterwards.
Albertus and Menaldo summarize the complexities of politics during this period: “universal suffrage enabled mass participation in elections, and the constitution enabled those elections to produce strong executives. But on the other hand, the dominant social actors—the agro-commercial oligarchy and the business class, many with economic or political ties to the United States—monopolized the seats in both houses of the national legislature” (2017, p. 262). The result of this combination was a consistent failure to redistribute (Slater et al., 2014, pp. 366–367).
This looks to be a promising case for H2. Yet the rise of the CPP/NPA is not a story of rightist repression and leftist reaction. First, there was profound disagreement within the left about whether armed rebellion was necessary or likely to be effective. The PKP in the late 1960s “renewed organizing for ‘parliamentary struggle’” (Abinales & Amoroso, 2005, p. 199) and “was content to slowly build front organizations, among students, workers, and peasants, not for the purpose of forcing a confrontation with the government, but for use as a springboard in a parliamentary struggle” (Jones, 1989, p. 25). Indeed, the KPK presciently claimed that violent rebellion would only “invite intensification of state repression and infiltration” (quoted in Fuller, 2011, p. 112).
Arrayed against this was the Mao-inspired emerging CPP, a young and “overwhelmingly petty-bourgeois” (Fuller, 2011, pp. 68–69) set of students and left activists led by Sison. They were believers in “armed revolution being the only road” (Fuller, 2011, p. 76). The “battle for influence between the old and new parties” (Abinales & Amoroso, 2005, p. 200) escalated from intra-KPK feuding in 1967 to the formation of the CPP in December 1968/January 1969 and then NPA in March 1969. The CPP/NPA violently clashed with KPK cadres as the split emerged (Fuller, 2011, p. 105). This process was remarkably similar to the pathway identified in H3—the KPK was working toward mainstream politics, while the more radical CPP saw mainstream electoral politics as a dead end.
Second, while Ferdinand Marcos was not a leftist, and policy did not move to the left during this period, he was also not in the late 1960s engaged in any particular crackdown against the left (that would come later). Instead, his main rivals were other elites with whom he battled over taxation levels and political power (Slater et al., 2014, p. 367). This is not a situation like Laos in 1958–9 or, indeed, the Philippines in 1946, of intensive state repression of the left that triggered revolt. Thus the onset of the NPA/CPP’s revolt thus provides evidence for both mechanisms.

Exploring Other Leftist Pathways

Here I briefly explore other trajectories of non-insurgency identified in Table 1. We face a problem in finding cases of fully non-violent co-optation, however, since almost all of the southern Asian countries faced some degree of violence around the incorporation of the left. A clear out-of-sample supporting case is the PCI in Italy, but southern Asia’s countries either did not have full leftist incorporation or it was accompanied or preceded by leftist insurgency. This shows just how difficult it was to seamlessly or non-violently bring the left into the political arena—incorporation was a double-edged sword that both staved off revolution and triggered violent revolts.
Instead, I identify two cases in which incorporation windows did not exist and no leftist insurgency emerged (before the destruction of the non-violent left closed off future possibilities). The Indonesian Communist Party (PKI) captures the “riding two horses” outcome in Table 1—a disciplined, cohesive party that did not face a hard choice about democratic participation prior to its annihilation in 1965–66. It was an organized and popular electoral force, as evidenced by its showing in 1955’s national parliamentary elections and then regional elections in Java in 1957 and 1958 (Robinson, 2018, pp. 37–38). The 1955 elections provided the PKI with “previously unheard of political influence and opened the possibility that the party might come to power through parliamentary means” (Robinson, 2018, p. 44).
Yet the brief period of open national electoral politics in Indonesia came to an end in 1957 when Sukarno declared martial law and with the 1959 return to the 1945 Constitution and cancellation of a planned election. In the 1957–1965 period of Guided Democracy, the PKI remained a legal political party, but focused on mass mobilization: “the shift away from electoral politics and toward the politics of mobilization did nothing to weaken the party’s popularity. Indeed, the PKI proved to be exceptionally adept in the work of mass mobilization” (Robinson, 2018, p. 44).
The party continued to pursue power through non-electoral means, becoming an increasingly close ally of Sukarno (Slater, 2010). At the same time, the PKI “was a legal party with no armed wing and no plans for revolution” (Robinson, 2018, p. 43). Thus there was no incorporation trade-off at hand—it could hold open the door to electoral involvement while also keeping a foot in non-electoral mass mobilization and elite maneuvering. The PKI was then cut down by the army at the height of the PKI’s power in 1965–66, and the hard left violently eliminated from Indonesian politics. No incorporation window emerged prior to the left being wiped out by the military.
The Pakistani left in the 1940s and early 1950s is an example of a divided and marginal political force that never had a opportunity to make major mainstream political advances: it is an instance of the lower-right cell in Table 1. The left in Pakistan was divided deeply along linguistic and geographical lines. The peasant mobilizations of East Bengal were very different than the Punjab heartland of the Pakistan Communist Party (PCP), while the PCP also faced criticism from other leftist intellectuals and political parties (Ali, 2011). There was little chance of a major leftist breakthrough in the face of both its own limitations and a profoundly hostile state apparatus: “The repression of Communist activities in Pakistan since 1947 has severely hampered the ability of party leaders to organize a large following” (Franda, 1970, p. 589).
Scattered peasant uprisings in East Pakistan, alleged Communist involvement in the Rawalpindi Conspiracy of 1951, and the increasingly pro-American stance of the Pakistani state elite combined to limit communist freedom of maneuver. When the PCP made some inroads in East Pakistan in 1954, it was rapidly banned by the state and repressed, in a preview of the military-bureaucratic nexus that would soon place Pakistan on the road to authoritarian rule (Jaffrelot, 2015).
There simply was not a real incorporation window, and the CPP did not lead a mobilized and cohesive left. Thereafter, even under formal periods of democracy, leftists, whether legal parties like the National Awami Party (NAP) or underground communist cells, were never able to carve out much space in a polity dominated by an anti-communist army and bureaucracy. Though some leftists became involved in the Baloch insurgency of the 1960s, the left was not a prime mover in this revolt. Instead, leftist forces were focused in student and labor groups that could generate street power but had a limited electoral role.
As in Indonesia, state policy ultimately made the idea of a leftist electoral breakthrough irrelevant to Pakistan. In both countries, the Cold War and powerful anti-communist militaries severely limited the space for leftist parties in mainstream politics. By contrast, the comparatively more insulated contexts of India, Sri Lanka, Burma, and Bangladesh are where we see the greatest freedom for the left in mainstream politics, and both the greatest involvement by leftist electoral forces and most robust leftist insurgencies. This international context helps us understand where and why incorporation windows emerged.

Conclusions

Influential research on revolution and regimes has framed revolutionary forces as reactive—the state and the elite set the stage that determines the incentives of the rest. This paper has suggested greater agency among prospective revolutionaries and their ideological rivals. There is a systematic path to revolt that finds its origins in disputes within the left about electoral politics. Rather than a reaction to rightist repression or the specter of authoritarianism, this was often a course consciously chosen by ideologically committed cadres with plausible alternative strategies. These other strategies, in turn, were often pursued by social democratic rivals in structurally-similar contexts. As a result, a surprising number of leftist rebels launched rebellion not against right-wing oligarchs, but rather center-left and socialist elected governments.
This finding does not invalidate H2’s alternative; there are indeed cases that align with the “undemocratic democracies” mechanism of leftist revolt, as in Laos, 1987 Sri Lanka, 1974 Bangladesh, and the Philippines in 1946. However, it appears to be less dominant than existing literature has allowed. Leftist insurgency is characterized by “equifinality” (George and Bennett, 2005)—there are multiple pathways to onset that cluster into a small number of clearly-identifiable mechanisms. Methodologically, the research design here allowed both a careful examination of cases and a set of comparisons that provided a valuable mix of breadth and depth. This blend of medium- and small-N work may be worth pursuing more broadly in political violence research—conflicts are sufficiently rare and heterogeneous to make deep investigation worthwhile, but common enough to make comparison essential.
These dynamics may not be unique to southern Asia. A systematic global study of this phenomenon will have to await future work, but a brief external validity check suggests that there may have been similar dynamics in Cold War Latin America. As in southern Asia, there were certainly leftist revolts under autocracy: Castro’s Movement of July 26 in Cuba, the FMLN in El Salvador, ELN in Bolivia, and several insurgencies in Guatemala occurred under dictatorship. Yet in Colombia (ELN, FARC, M19), Peru (Sendero Luminoso, MRTA, MIR), and Venezuela (Bandera Roja) we see plausible cases of electoral democracy being the site of armed leftist mobilization. There are also more ambiguous cases, as with leftist groups in Argentina and Uruguay in the 1960s and 1970s that existed, with varying levels and forms of violence, across different regime types.
As in southern Asia, Cold War dynamics were very important both in inspiring revolts and shaping regimes’ responses to them, but these international forces interacted with domestic contexts in which regime type and political systems played a key role in determining whether and how open revolt broke out (Policzer, 2009; Wickham-Crowley, 1992). There seem to be similar pathways to radical redistributive insurgency across regions, tentatively suggesting external validity to the arguments advanced in this paper.
Understanding the conditions under which we see radical and violent redistributive insurgency requires further empirical research. First, further cross-national comparisons are necessary to probe, deepen, and complicate the theory while moving beyond the limitations of this paper’s research design. A deeper examination of Latin America during the Cold War is a natural candidate for systematic further exploration. Western Europe also experienced both leftist incorporation and (admittedly small) leftist terrorist campaigns during the Cold War (Della Porta, 1995). These cases provide an opportunity to more systematically explore the domestic and international conditions affecting the ideological structure of intra-left competition and the existence of incorporation windows.
More provocatively, Kalyvas (2015) has argued that radical Islamist groups have come to occupy the role that leftist revolutionaries occupied during the Cold War. While these groups have largely emerged in non-democratic countries, there still might be relevant similarities that can extend the basic logic of the argument: they have demanded radical changes to the political status quo, articulated fundamentally different understandings of the polity, and sought to capture the commanding heights of state power. There are a wide variety of contexts in which movements face a difficult choice between the revolutionary road and the parliamentary path.
Second, there is a need for more fine-grained sub-national comparisons that can improve our understanding of where and when precisely the radical left successfully mobilized for war, and when and where these movements were unable to generate momentum (i.e., Chandra & García-Ponce, 2019). This can help us understand, for example, why West Bengal was so violent in the 1960s while Kerala was substantially less so, despite both having vibrant left movements, or why some areas of the Philippines proved more receptive than others to both the Huk and NPA insurgencies. This is an area in which the micro-level strand of civil war research (Kalyvas, 2006) can be productively fused with the more meso -level approach of this article to uncover how broad political trends actually played out on the ground.
There are two broader theoretical insights that emerge from this article. The first is that democracy can have complex, often cross-cutting, effects on conflict and mobilization (Jones & Lupu, 2018). In a number of the cases, we see a fascinating dynamic in which electoral democracy breaks apart a potential revolutionary coalition, but in doing so pushes the radical rump toward open revolt. This forestalls the overthrows of regime that scholars like Skocpol have focused on—but opens the door to grim, often decades-long, insurgent and counterinsurgent wars that carry a high human cost. The incorporation of the left in 20th-century Asia was a bloody, protracted, and ambivalent process.
The second theoretical point is the role of political ideology in the debates that triggered insurgent revolt. Individuals and groups with similar structural characteristics often adopted radically opposed views of politics, in ways that cannot be easily mapped onto their position on an income distribution. There is nothing obvious about Siraj Sikdar’s class status in 1972 Bangladesh that would make him seem objectively more likely to pursue Maoism than Mujib-ism. Transnational ideological currents were grafted onto local political contexts in highly contingent ways, with enormous consequences. The study of conflict needs to more systematically theorize and measure the origins, diffusion, and evolution of ideology to better understand how these understandings of political life became fused to both revolutionary violence and parliamentary incorporation (Costalli & Ruggeri, 2015; Gutierrez- Sanín & Wood, 2014; Hoover Green, 2018; Leader Maynard, 2019; Staniland, 2015; Stewart, 2020; Straus, 2015). The leaders and foot soldiers of revolution, counter-revolution, and center-left incorporation all pursued their visions at high personal and political cost, often in the face of tremendously long odds; their ideas deserve to be taken seriously.

Acknowledgments

The author thanks Michael Albertus, Sarah Daly, Jon DePoyster, Evgeny Finkel, Stathis Kalyvas, Monika Nalepa, Dan Slater, Drew Stommes, Andres Uribe, Adam Ziegfeld, three anonymous reviewers, and the editors of Comparative Political Studies for excellent feedback. Will Howell organized a stimulating faculty workshop on the manuscript in the University of Chicago Department of Political Science. Noah Schouela, Winston Berg, Liya Khan, Bryan Popoola, Catherine Grothe, Dan Gamarnik, Madeleine Stevens, Erik Mueller, and Wenyan Deng provided exceptional research assistance.

Declaration of Conflicting Interests

The author declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Funding

The author disclosed receipt of the following financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article: Funded was provided by the Pearson Institute for Global Conflict and Conflict Resolution, the Smith Richardson Foundation, and by award W911-NF- 1710044 from the Department of Defense and U.S. Army Research Office/Army Research Laboratory under the Minerva Research Initiative. The views expressed are those of the author(s) and should not be attributed to the Department of Defense or the Army Research Office/Army Research Laboratory.

ORCID iD

Footnotes

1. Ron (2001) points to the Sendero Luminoso in 1980 Peru as a similarly-puzzling case for the conventional wisdom.
2. Cederman et al. (2010) for ethnic revolts, Sambanis (2001) for ethnic/ideological, and Kalyvas and Balcells (2010) on types of wars.
4. Suggesting the extent of factionalism even within the insurgency, an anti-Mazumdar Maoist group, the Dakshin DEsh, became the basis for the Maoist Communist Centre, which became one of the major parts of the current CPI-Maoist.

References

Abinales P. N., Amoroso D. J. (2005). State and society in the Philippines. Rowman & Littlefield.
Acemoglu D., Robinson J. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge University Press.
Adhikari A. (2014). The bullet and the ballot box: The story of Nepal’s Maoist Revolution. Verso.
Albertus M. (2015). Autocracy and redistribution: The politics of land reform (1st ed.). Cambridge University Press.
Albertus M., Menaldo V. (2017). Authoritarianism and the elite origins of democracy. Cambridge University Press.
Ali K. A. (2011). Communists in a Muslim land: Cultural debates in Pakistan’s early years. Modern Asian Studies, 45(3), 501–534.
Alles A. C. (1976). Insurgency, 1971: An account of the april insurrection in Sri Lanka. Trade Exchange.
Amin N. (1985). The pro-chinese communist movement in Bangladesh. Journal of Contemporary Asia, 15(3), 349–360.
Amin N. (1986). Maoism in Bangladesh: The case of the East Bengal Sarbohara Party. Asian Survey, 26(7), 759–773.
Balcells L., Kalyvas S. (2015). Revolutionary rebels and the Marxist paradox. Georgetown University and Oxford University.
Bandyopadhyay S. (2008). The story of an aborted revolution: Communist insurgency in post-independence West Bengal, 1948–50. Journal of South Asian Development, 3(1), 1–32.
Boix C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge University Press.
Boix C. (2008). Economic roots of civil wars and revolutions in the contemporary world. World Politics, 60(3), 390–437.
Boix C., Miller M., Rosato S. (2013). A complete data set of political regimes, 1800–2007. Comparative Political Studies, 46(12), 1523–1554.
Brady H. E., Collier D. (Eds.). (2010). Rethinking social inquiry: Diverse tools, shared standards (2nd ed.). Rowman & Littlefield.
Brown N. J. (2012). When victory is not an option: Islamist movements in Arab politics. Cornell University Press.
Callahan M. P. (2003). Making enemies: War and state building in Burma. Cornell University Press.
Cederman L. E., Wimmer A., Min B. (2010). Why do ethnic groups rebel? New data and analysis. World Politics 62(1), 87–119.
Chandra K., García-Ponce O. (2019). Why ethnic subaltern-led parties crowd out armed organizations: Explaining maoist violence in India. World Politics, 71(2), 367–416.
Chandraprema C. A. (1991). Sri Lanka, the years of terror: The J.V.P. insurrection, 1987-1989 (1st ed.). Lake House Bookshop.
Chibber V. (2003). Locked in place: State-building and late industrialization in India. Princeton University Press.
Costalli S., Ruggeri A. (2015). Indignation, ideologies, and armed mobilization: Civil war in Italy, 1943–45. International Security, 40(2), 119–157.
Cunningham K. G. (2014). Inside the politics of self-determination. Oxford University Press.
Daly S. Z. (2014). The dark side of power-sharing: Middle managers and civil war recurrence. Comparative Politics, 46(3), 333–353.
Della Porta D. (1995). Social Movements, political violence, and the state: A comparative analysis of Italy and Germany. Cambridge University Press.
Fearon J. D., Laitin D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. The American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.
Finkel Evgeny (2017). Ordinary Jews: Choice and Survival during the Holocaust. Princeton University Press.
Finkel E., Gehlbach S. (2020). Reform and rebellion in weak states. Cambridge University Press.
Franda M. F. (1970). Communism and Regional Politics in East Pakistan. Asian Survey, 10(7), 588–606.
Franda M. F. (1971). Radical politics in West Bengal (1st ed.). The MIT Press.
Fuller K. (2011). A movement divided: Philippine communism, 1957-1986. University of the Philippines Press.
Geddes B., Wright J., Frantz E. (2014). Autocratic breakdown and regime transitions: A new data set. Perspectives on Politics, 12(2), 313–331.
George A. L., Bennett A. (2005). Case studies and theory development in the social sciences. MIT Press.
Goodwin J. (2001). No other way out: States and revolutionary movements, 1945-1991. Cambridge University Press.
Goodwin J., Skocpol T. (1989). Explaining revolutions in the contemporary third world. Politics & Society, 17(4), 489–509.
Green A. H. (2018). The commander’s dilemma: Violence and restraint in wartime. Cornell University Press.
Gunaratna R. (1990). Sri Lanka, a lost revolution? The inside story of the JVP. Institute of Fundamental Studies.
Haggard S., Kaufman R. R. (2012). Inequality and regime change: Democratic transitions and the stability of democratic rule. American Political Science Review, 106(3), 495–516.
Hegre H., Ellingsen T., Gates S., Gleditsch N. P. (2001). Toward a democratic civil peace? Democracy, political change, and civil war, 1816-1992. The American Political Science Review, 95(1), 33–48.
Horowitz D. L. (1985). Ethnic groups in conflict. University of California Press.
Huntington S. P. (1968). Political order in changing societies. Yale University Press.
Hutt M. (Ed.) (2004). Himalayan People’s War: Nepal’s Maoist Rebellion. (1st ed.). Indiana University Press.
Jaffrelot C. (2015). The Pakistan paradox: Instability and resilience. Oxford University Press.
Jahan R. (1974). Bangladesh in 1973: Management of factional politics. Asian Survey, 14(2), 125–135.
Jha P. (2015). Battles of the New Republic: A contemporary history of Nepal (1st ed.). Hurst.
Jones G. R. (1989). Red revolution: Inside the Philippine guerrilla movement. Westview Press.
Jones Z. M., Lupu Y. (2018). Is there more violence in the middle? American Journal of Political Science, 62(3), 652–667.
Kalyvas S. (2015). Is ISIS a revolutionary group and if yes, what are the implications? Perspectives on Terrorism, 9(4), 42–47.
Kalyvas S. N. (2006). The logic of violence in civil war. Cambridge University Press.
Kalyvas S. N., Balcells L. (2010). International system and technologies of rebellion: How the end of the cold war shaped internal conflict. American Political Science Review, 104(3), 415–429.
Kalyvas S. N. (2019). The landscape of political violence. In Chenoweth E., English R., Gofas A., Kalyvas S. N. (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Terrorism. Oxford University Press.
Kennedy J., Purushotham S. (2012). Beyond naxalbari: A comparative analysis of maoist insurgency and counterinsurgency in independent India. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 54(4), 832–862.
Kerkvliet B. J. (1977). The Huk rebellion: A study of peasant revolt in the Philippines. University of California Press.
King G., Keohane R. O., Verba S. (1994). Designing social inquiry: Scientific inference in qualitative research. Princeton University Press.
Kohli A. (1990). Democracy and discontent: India’s growing crisis of governability. Cambridge University Press.
Krause P. (2017). Rebel power: Why national movements compete, fight, and win. Cornell University Press.
Kydd A., Walter B. F. (2002). Sabotaging the peace: The politics of extremist violence. International Organization, 56(2), 263–96.
Lintner B. (1990). The rise and fall of the Communist Party of Burma (CPB). SEAP Publications.
Lintner B. (1999). Burma in revolt: Opium and insurgency since 1948. (2nd ed.). Silkworm Books.
Leader Maynard J. (2019). Ideology and armed conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 56(5), 635–649.
Lüthi L. M. (2008). The sino-soviet split: Cold war in the communist world. Princeton University Press.
McAdams A. J. (2017). Vanguard of the revolution: The global idea of the communist party. Princeton University Press.
Mahoney J. (2010). After KKV: The new methodology of qualitative research. World Politics, 62(1), 120–147.
Maniruzzaman T. (1975). Bangladesh: An unfinished revolution? The Journal of Asian Studies, 34(4), 891–911.
Maniruzzaman T. (1980). The Bangladesh revolution and its aftermath. Bangladesh Books International.
Masoom A. L. (2000). Dilemmas of a military ruler: A political study of the Zia Regime. Afsar Brothers.
Mohaiemen N. (2006). Kothai Aj Shei Shiraj Sikder (Where Today Is That Shiraj Sikder)? Terrorists or Guerrillas in the Mist. Sarai Reader, 6, 296–311.
Moore B. (1966). Social origins of dictatorship and democracy: Lord and peasant in the making of the modern world. Beacon Press.
Moten A. R. (1980). Party politics in Bangladesh: The parliamentary era. Journal of South Asian and Middle Eastern Studies, 3(4), 66–83.
Paige J. M. (1975). Agrarian revolution: Social movements and export agriculture in the underdeveloped world. Free Press.
Pearlman W. (2008). Spoiling inside and out: Internal political contestation and the Middle East peace process. International Security, 33(3), 79–109.
Policzer P. (2009). Rise and fall of repression in chile. University of Notre Dame Press.
Riaz A. (2016). Bangladesh: A political history since independence. I.B. Tarius & Co. Ltd.
Robinson G. B. (2018). The killing season: A history of the Indonesian Massacres, 1965-66. Princeton University Press.
Ron J. (2001). Ideology in context: Explaining Sendero Luminoso’s tactical escalation. Journal of Peace Research, 38(5), 569–592.
Sambanis N. (2001). Do ethnic and nonethnic civil wars have the same causes? A theoretical and empirical inquiry (Part 1). Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45(3), 259–282.
Sanín F. G., Wood E. J. (2014). Ideology in civil war: Instrumental adoption and beyond. Journal of Peace Research, 51(2), 213–226.
Scott J. C. (1976). The moral economy of the peasant: Rebellion and subsistence in Southeast Asia. Yale University Press.
Scott J. C. (1979). Revolution in the revolution: Peasants and commissars. Theory and Society, 7(1–2), 97–134.
Selznick P. (1952). The organizational weapon: A study of bolshevik strategy and tactics. (1st ed.). McGraw-Hill.
Shefter M. (1994). Political parties and the State: The American historical experience. Princeton Studies in American Politics. Princeton University Press.
Silverstein J. (1990). Civil war and rebellion in Burma. Journal of Southeast Asian Studies, 21(1), 114–134.
Skocpol T. (1979). States and social revolutions: A comparative analysis of France, Russia, and China. Cambridge University Press.
Skocpol T., Migdal J. S., Paige J. M., Scott J. C., Wolf E. R. (1982). What makes peasants revolutionary? Comparative Politics, 14(3), 351–375.
Slater D. (2010). Ordering power: Contentious politics and authoritarian leviathans in Southeast Asia. Cambridge University Press.
Slater D., Smith B., Nair G. (2014). Economic origins of democratic breakdown? The redistributive model and the postcolonial state. Perspectives on Politics, 12(2), 353–374.
Smith M. J. (1991). Burma: Insurgency and the politics of ethnicity. Zed Books.
Smith M. J. (1999). Burma: Insurgency and the politics of ethnicity (2nd ed.). Zed Books.
Snyder J. L. (2000). From voting to violence: Democratization and nationalist conflict. W. W. Norton & Company.
Staniland P. (2014). Networks of rebellion: Explaining insurgent cohesion and collapse (1st ed.). Cornell University Press.
Staniland P. (2015). Militias, ideology, and the state. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 59(5), 770–793.
Stedman S. J. (1997). Spoiler problems in peace processes. International Security, 22(2), 5–53.
Stewart M. (2020). Micro-foundations of the vanguard: The origins of revolutionary leftist rebel groups (Working paper). American University.
Straus S. (2015). Making and unmaking nations: War, leadership, and genocide in modern Africa. Cornell University Press.
Stuart-Fox M. (1997). A history of Laos. Cambridge University Press.
Svolik M. W. (2012). The politics of authoritarian rule. Cambridge University Press.
Thurber C. (2015). Between Mao and Gandhi: Strategies of violence and nonviolence in revolutionary movements (PhD dissertation). Tufts University.
Vreeland J. R. (2008). The effect of political regime on civil war: Unpacking anocracy. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52(3), 401–425.
Wickham-Crowley T. P. (1992). Guerrillas and revolution in Latin America: A comparative study of insurgents and regimes since 1956. Princeton University Press.
Wolf E. R. (1969). Peasant wars of the twentieth century. Harper & Row.
Wood E. J. (2000). Forging democracy from below: Insurgent transitions in South Africa and El Salvador. Cambridge Studies in Comparative Politics, Cambridge University Press.
Wood E. J. (2001). An insurgent path to democracy popular mobilization, economic interests, and regime transition in South Africa and El Salvador. Comparative Political Studies, 34(8), 862–888.
Wood R. M, Thomas J. L. (2017). Women on the frontline: Rebel group ideology and women’s participation in violent rebellion. Journal of Peace Research, 54(1), 31–46.

Biographies

Paul Staniland is an associate professor of Political Science at the University of Chicago and Nonresident Scholar in the South Asia Program at the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. His research focuses on political violence and international security in South Asia.

Supplementary Material

Supplemental Material

Please find the following supplemental material visualised and available to download via Figshare in the display box below. Where there are more than one item, you can scroll through each tab to see each separate item.

Please note all supplemental material carries the same license as the article it is here associated with

File (cpsappendix6-1-20.pdf)

Cite article

Cite article

Cite article

OR

Download to reference manager

If you have citation software installed, you can download article citation data to the citation manager of your choice

Share options

Share

Share this article

Share with email
EMAIL ARTICLE LINK
Share on social media

Share access to this article

Create a link to share a read only version of this article with your colleagues and friends. For more information view the Sage Journals article sharing page.

Please read and accept the terms and conditions and check the box to generate a sharing link.

terms and conditions

Information, rights and permissions

Information

Published In

Article first published online: July 8, 2020
Issue published: March 2021

Keywords

  1. Civil war
  2. democratization and regime change
  3. political regimes
  4. qualitative methods
  5. terrorism

Rights and permissions

© The Author(s) 2020.
Request permissions for this article.
Request Permissions

Authors

Affiliations

Paul Staniland

Notes

Paul Staniland, University of Chicago, 5828 South University Avenue, Chicago, IL 60637, USA. Email: [email protected]

Metrics and citations

Metrics

Journals metrics

This article was published in Comparative Political Studies.

VIEW ALL JOURNAL METRICS

Article usage*

Total views and downloads: 3924

*Article usage tracking started in December 2016


Altmetric

See the impact this article is making through the number of times it’s been read, and the Altmetric Score.
Learn more about the Altmetric Scores



Articles citing this one

Receive email alerts when this article is cited

Web of Science: 6 view articles Opens in new tab

Crossref: 4

  1. Conceptualizing the Paradigm Shift from Prosocial Communism to Violent...
    Go to citation Crossref Google Scholar
  2. The Evolution of Civil Wars Research: From Civil War to Political Viol...
    Go to citation Crossref Google Scholar
  3. Foundations of the Vanguard: the origins of leftist rebel groups
    Go to citation Crossref Google Scholar
  4. Dynamics of peace or legacy of rebel governance? Patterns of cooperati...
    Go to citation Crossref Google Scholar

Figures and tables

Figures & Media

Tables

View Options

View options

PDF/ePub

View PDF/ePub

Get access

Access options

If you have access to journal content via a personal subscription, university, library, employer or society, select from the options below:


Alternatively, view purchase options below:

Purchase 24 hour online access to view and download content.

Access journal content via a DeepDyve subscription or find out more about this option.