Skip to main content
Log in

A tale of minorities: evidence on religious ethics and entrepreneurship

  • Published:
Journal of Economic Growth Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Does Protestantism favour entrepreneurship more than Catholicism does? We provide a novel way to answer this question by comparing Protestant and Catholic minorities using Swiss census data. Exploiting the strong adhesion of religious minorities to their denomination’ ethical principles and the historical determination of the geographical distribution of denominations across Swiss cantons, we find that Protestantism is associated with a significantly higher propensity for entrepreneurship. The estimated difference ranges between 1.5 and 3.2 % points, it is larger the smaller the size of the religious minority, it is mainly driven by prime age male entrepreneurs and it stands up to a number of robustness checks. No effects are found when comparing religious majorities, suggesting that the implications of religious ethical norms on economic outcomes emerge only when such norms are fully internalized.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, only 20 % of western Europeans believe in life after death, although 70 % are self-declared Christians (International Social Survey Programme Religion II data, 1998).

  2. Unlike Weber and other authors, we do not investigate the historical process that led to the development of capitalism. Instead, we provide an empirical investigation of the religious ethical determinants of economic behaviour in a contemporary economy.

  3. The proportion of entrepreneurs who engage in petty trades and ventures is minor: less than 5 % are involved in elementary occupation according to the ISCO classification (source: 1990 Swiss Census).

  4. The superiority of meditation over work derives from the ancient Greeks and Romans, who viewed work as dishonourable. (See, e.g., Canfora 1989).

  5. According to Pope John Paul II (Laborem Exercens: Encyclical Letter on Human Work, 1981): “Sweat and toil, which work necessarily involves in the present condition of the human race, present the Christian and everyone who is called to follow Christ with the possibility of sharing lovingly in the work that Christ came to do”.

  6. Luther’s and Calvin’s views differed regarding the morality of trade activity. Luther looked at trade as a way to take advantage of the needs of the others, while Calvin considered trade and commerce useful and that those engaged in trade provide a service to society at a risk to themselves.

  7. This is especially the case in Calvinism. According to the Calvinist concept of predestination, God decides a person’s salvation or damnation before his or her birth, but it is hidden to the person, who can do nothing to alter his or her fate. Worldly success is regarded as a sign of being among the select group that will be saved from damnation by God (Becker and Woessmann 2009; Arrunada 2010).

  8. Like other German-speaking countries, Switzerland imposes a Church tax which is levied by the cantonal authorities on behalf of recognized churches. The information on the tax payers’ religious affiliation is typically collected upon the individual registration with a church or through administrative procedures. The reported Census religious affiliation status is an independent measure that is not related to the payment of the Church tax and therefore should not be affected by an under-reporting bias.

  9. Districts in Switzerland corresponds to the intermediate level of aggregation between NUTS3 (cantons) and municipalities. There are 181 districts as of January 1st 2001, the date we use as reference to standardize geographic division across years.

  10. In Nordwestschweiz, Ostschweiz and Région Lémanique the proportion of minority Catholics is 1 percent or less; in Ticino and Zentralschweiz there are no majority Protestants while in the canton of Zürich minority Protestants are not present.

  11. The proportion of unemployed in the sample is about 3 %.

  12. In the Swiss census they are generally defined as independents.

  13. Such distribution is stable across cantons and language groups.

  14. The result emerges both when we consider the whole time span of the European Social Survey, from 2002 to 2012, and when we focus on 2002 only. Minority Protestants are found to be more likely to be very religious (i.e. scoring 7 or more in a scale of religiousness from 0 to 10) than majority Protestants by 32 % points in 2002, whereas the difference is 13 % points in the case of minority Catholics.

  15. See the historical maps in the online appendix.

  16. The data is matched by district, adjusting for the changes in the definition of Swiss districts that occurred after 1870. The districts of Dietikon, Wasseramt, Inn, Plessur, Prättigau-Davos and Surselva were dropped because an unambiguous correspondence with the Boppart, Falkinger, Grossmann, Woitek, and Wüthrich’s classification could not be established.

  17. For instance within minorities, parents push their offsprings to privilege same-religion friends and individuals are pressed to marry same-religion partners.

  18. In the following sections we provide ample evidence on how entrepreneurship does not depend on the localization of Protestant and Catholic minorities in specific areas.

  19. Nunziata and Rocco (2014) provide ample evidence in support of the comparability of religious minorities.

  20. The relationship between entrepreneurship and religious attachment is assumed to be linear for exposition purposes only, but linearity is not required.

  21. More precisely, these dummies take the value of 1 if the market share of individual i’s religion in i’s district of residence at time t is larger than 60 % or smaller than 25 %, respectively. The majority/minority dummies vary at the individual level since they depend on the individual’s particular religion. See the robustness checks below that adopt alternative thresholds and an alternative model specification.

  22. Appendix 3 provides a table of all main estimated coefficients.

  23. Since Bern includes 80 % of minority Catholics, it is not surprising that its exclusion reduces the precision of the estimated difference between minorities. The corresponding p-value is nonetheless 0.106. The exclusion of any other canton does not affect the estimates’ precision. Estimates not reported, available upon request.

  24. Most Swiss residents were educated (77.6 %) or work (54.2 %) in the same municipality they reside. Only 2.4 % were educated and 8.9 % work in a different Canton.

  25. See the historical maps in the online appendix.

  26. The median municipality population in 2000 was 870.

  27. The point estimates at the canton level are very similar to those obtained by Nunziata and Rocco (2014) estimating the same model on data from the regions of the former Holy Roman Empire, i.e. Austria, Belgium, the Czech Republic, Germany, Luxemburg, Slovenia, Trentino, the eastern part of France, and the western Polish regions of Pomerania, Lubuskie, and Dolnoslaskie. The estimated effects in that case range between 3.6 % points (whole former Holy Roman Empire sample) and 5.5 % points (German regions only).

  28. We have redefined religious majorities and minorities as follows. Majority Protestants (resp. Catholics) are those individual who declare to be Protestant (resp. Catholic) and resides in districts where a Protestant (resp. Catholic) majority was recorded in 1870 regardless of the subsequent evolution. The same is done for minorities.

  29. Similar estimates are obtained when we adjust the baseline minority thresholds in 1870 to account for the lack of atheists at the time. Assuming an average atheist share equal to 6 % in 1990, this amounts to a 6 % adjustment applied to the 25 % baseline minority threshold.

  30. By considering only native individuals with Swiss citizenship, we have almost completely removed the issue of mobility from abroad and especially from the Catholic countries of Southern Europe. However, due to data limitations, our sample still includes second generation immigrants, who might have inherited a lower social status by their parents. To evaluate the influence of second generation immigrants on our estimates, we have estimated model (1) for 1970 only, i.e. when we expect the prevalence of second generation migrants to be negligible given that the most important immigration wave from Catholic countries to Switzerland took place after World War II (FSO 1998). Also in this case our results are almost identical to the baseline.

  31. About 10 % of all entrepreneurs are 15–30 years of age.

  32. This difference implies that Zwingli did not recognise the only two sacraments retained by Luther, Baptism and the Eucharist, and that he considered even these two only symbols of a spiritual reality that is internal to the human being. Zwingli’s view also saw the liturgy and churches’ decorations as much more essential and rejected the conception of natural sin (contrary to Luther), as he believed that only awareness implies responsibility, so only people who are aware can sin (Sheldon 1984).

  33. Zwingli and Luther differed in their conception of the state as well. For Luther there is a separation between spiritual and worldly matters (the theory of the two kingdoms), with the latter administered by the state and commanded by God himself as remediation for human evil, and for this reason to be obeyed under all circumstances, a conception that leads to a form of absolutism. For Zwingli the state is instrumental in ensuring people’s welfare, so individuals should be sympathetic to the state and their fellow citizens. Therefore, Zwingli’s ideal state is a republic. However, the state also has the right to defend and preserve morality and ethics, so the state and religion are interlinked, a conception that will be brought to the extreme by Calvin, who transformed Genève into a sort of intolerant theocracy with his “ordonnances ecclesiastiques”.

  34. The Helvetic confession, which defines the common traits of the Reformed churches, parallels the Augsburg Confession (1530). The Augsburg Confession, the cornerstone of Lutheranism, defines the common traits of the evangelical churches. Practically, the adoption of the Helvetic Confession established the division between the reformed and the evangelical churches.

  35. See http://www.kirchenbund.ch/en.

References

  • Andersen, T. B., Bentzen, J., Dalgaard, C.-J., & Sharp, P. (2013). Pre-reformation roots of the protestant ethic, Working Paper 137, Centre for Competitive Advantage in the Global Economy, Department of Economics, The University of Warwick.

  • Arrunada, B. (2010). Protestants and Catholics: Similar work ethic, different social ethic. Economic Journal, 120, 890–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basten, C., & Betz, F. (2013). Beyond work ethic: Religion, individual, and political preferences. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 5(3), 67–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S., & Woessmann, L. (2009). Was Weber wrong? A human capital theory of protestant economic history. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(2), 531–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A., Topa, G., & Verdier, T. (2004). Religious Intermarriage and Socialization in the United States. Journal of Political Economy, 112(3), 615–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A., & Verdier, T. (2000). Beyond the melting pot: Cultural transmission, marriage, and the evolution of ethnic and religious traits. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 955–988.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A., & Verdier, T. (2001). The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. Journal of Economic Theory, 97, 298–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonhoeffer, D. (1959). The cost of discipleship. New York: Collier Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boppart, T., Falkinger, J., Grossmann, V., Woitek, U., & Wüthrich, G. (2013). Under which conditions does religion affect educational outcomes? Explorations in Economic History, 50(2), 242–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canfora, L. (1989). Una società premoderna. Lavoro, morale, scrittura in Grecia. Dedalo.

  • Cantoni, D. (2012). Adopting a new religion: the case of protestantism in 16th century Germany. The Economic Journal, 122(560), 502–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantoni, D. (2015). The economic effects of the Protestant Reformation: Testing the Weber hypothesis in the German Lands. Journal of the European Economic Association, forthcoming.

  • Cohen, A., & Hill, P. (2007). Religion as culture: Religious individualism and collectivism among American Catholics, Jews, and Protestants. Journal of Personality, 75(4), 709–742.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen-Zada, D. (2006). Preserving religious identity through education: Economic analysis and evidence from the US. Journal of Urban Economics, 60, 372–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuervo, A. (2005). Individual and environmental determinants of entrepreneurship. International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal, 1, 293–311. doi:10.1007/s11365-005-2591-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, D. (2013). The economists of the reformation: An overview of reformation teaching concerning work, wealth, and interest. In SAGE Open (pp. 1–9).

  • Finke, R., & Stark, R. (1998). Reply to Olson: Religious choice and competition. American Sociological Review, 63, 761–766.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon, B. (2003). The Swiss Reformation. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Head, R. (1998). Religious coexistence and confessional conflict in the Vier Dörfer. Practices of toleration in Eastern Switzerland, 1525–1615. In J. C. Laursen & C. J. Nederman (Eds.), Beyond the persecuting society: Religious toleration before the enlightenment. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herzog, J. J., & Schaff, P. (1908). The new Schaff–Herzog encyclopedia of religious knowledge. New York: Funk and Wagnalls Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes, T. J., & Schmitz, J. A. (1990). A theory of entrepreneurship and its application to the study of business transfers. Journal of Political Economy, 87, 265–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kihlstrom, R., & Laffont, J. (1979). A general equilibrium theory of firm formation based on risk aversion. Journal of Political Economy, 87, 719–748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. (1978). On the size distribution of business firms. Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 508–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, A., & Sharp, H. (1962). Religious preference and worldly success. American Sociological Review, 27(2), 218–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCleary, R. M., & Barro, R. J. (2006). Religion and economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2), 49–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McClelland, D. (1961). The Achieving Society. D. Van Nostrand, reprinted in 2010 by Martino Fine Books, New York.

  • Meyer, H. (1976). Der zweite kappeler Krieg: Die Krise der schweizerischen Reformation. Zurich: Hans Rohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunziata, L., & Rocco, L. (2014). The Protestant ethic and entrepreneurship: Evidence from religious minorities in the former Holy Roman Empire. Discussion Paper 53566, MPRA.

  • Parker, S. (2005). The economics of entrepreneurship: What we know and what we don’t. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 1(1), 1–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S., & Belghitar, Y. (2006). What happens to nascent entrepreneurs? An econometric analysis of the PSED. Small Business Economics, 27, 81–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, S. C. (2004). The economics of self-employment and entrepreneurship. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pettegree, A. (2000). The Reformation World. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Renneboog, L., & Spaenjers, C. (2012). Religion, economic attitudes, and household finance. Oxford Economic Papers, 64(1), 103–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaff, P. (1882). History of the Christian Church. Vol. VIII: Modern Christianity. The Swiss Reformation. Grand Rapids, MI: Christian Classics Ethereal Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheldon, H. (1984). History of the Christian Church. Vol. III The modern Church. New York: Thomas Y. Crowell & Co.

  • Stark, R. (1998). Catholic contexts: Competition, commitment and innovation. Review of Religious Research, 39, 197–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stark, R., Finke, R., & Iannaccone, L. (1995). Pluralism and piety: England and Wales, 1851. American Sociological Review, 34, 431–444.

  • Swiss Federal Statistical Office (FSO). (1998). Two Centuries of Swiss Demographic History. Neuchâtel.

  • Swiss Federal Statistical Office (FSO). (2014). Federal Population Census, 1970–2000. Neuchâtel.

  • Tawney, R. H. (1926). Religion and the rise of capitalism. New York, NY: Mentor Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilgher, A. (1958). Homo faber: Work through the ages. Chicago: Regnery.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1904). The Protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism, Vol. reprinted 2001. Roxbury Publishing Company.

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank Giulia Tura for excellent research assistance, Ulrich Woitek for providing the data on religious denomination shares in 1870, four anonymous referees and the seminar participants at the University of Bologna, the University of Milan, the Luxembourg Institute of Socio-Economic Research, the conference of the Association for the Study of Religion, Economics, and Culture in Orange, California and the European Society for Population Economics in Braga for comments and suggestions. A particular thank to Andrea Ichino and Giorgio Brunello who commented on earlier versions of this draft. We gratefully acknowledge the financial support provided by the University of Padova - Progetto d’Ateneo 2011—Grant No. CPDA113278. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luca Nunziata.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (zip 2429 KB)

Appendices

Appendix 1: The reform in Switzerland

At the beginning of the sixteenth century, Switzerland was composed of thirteen cantons—Uri, Schwytz, Unterwalden, and Lucerne (the four so-called Forest Cantons), Zug, Solothurn, Zürich, Glarus, Bern, Fribourg, Basel, Schaffhausen, and Appenzell—and a number of allied cities and dependent territories. Dependent territories were jointly administered by several cantons.

The Reformation in Switzerland is linked to the name of Ulrich Zwingli, a pastor in Zurich with an humanistic approach that was largely influenced by Erasmus’ ideas, and to a number of other leaders (e.g., Bucer, Bullinger, Calvin, Farel, Oecolampadius). Zwingli started preaching the need for reform of the Catholic Church at nearly the same time (1518) as Luther nailed his ninety-five theses to the doors of the Wittenberg Cathedral (1517). Zwingli’s ethical and moral criticisms of the Church where linked to the condemnation of the Swiss practice of serving as mercenaries for the European powers (Schaff 1882).

Although Zwingli’s and Luther’s theologies developed independently, they have many similarities, including the primacy of the scriptures over tradition, justification by faith alone and not good works, and universal priesthood without requiring the mediation of the clergy.

However, in several respects, Zwingli’s theology is the more radical. While Luther accepted Catholic tradition if it does not contrast with the scriptures, Zwingli wanted to quit any practice that was not explicitly grounded in the New Testament.Footnote 32

While in Luther’s view the new religion should be brought to the masses by the state, for Zwingli conversion should be achieved by means of persuasion and discussion, in line with his humanistic approach, as only reason should induce people to convert.Footnote 33

The Reformation spread from Zürich to many cantons, including St. Gallen (a former Catholic Prince-Abbacy), Basel, Bern, and Genève. The Forest Cantons and Zug opposed it fiercely, creating the league of the Five cantons, and called for the emperor’s support. War broke out in 1529 (the first War of Kappel), when Zürich and Bern attacked. A peace treaty favourable to Zürich and its allies was signed even before the war was fought, and the Reformation was declared free to spread in the dependent territories. In 1531 a second War of Kappel broke out, in which the five cantons attacked and eventually defeated the Reformed army and Zwingli, serving as a military chaplain, died in battle. Anticipating the Peace of Augsburg of 1555, the peace treaty established a principle similar to the “cuius regio eius religio”, where each canton was free to set its own religion. The primacy of Catholicism was favoured in the dependent territories and the Prince-Abbacy of St. Gallen was restored (Meyer 1976).

After Zwingli’s death, Calvin systematised and formalised the Swiss Reformed theology. Genève, Zürich, Bern, and Basel defined and agreed upon the common traits of their faith by means of the mutual consensus (1549), attenuating the more extreme spikes of Zwinglian doctrine. Next, in 1566 Bullinger prepared the (second) Helvetic Confession, which was published by the Elector Palatinate and adopted not only in the entire Reformed Switzerland but also in Scotland, France, Hungary, and Poland.Footnote 34

Religious tension continued in Switzerland until the eighteenth century but without major conflicts. The Catholic cantons promoted the re-catholicisation of the dependent territories that had previously turned to the Reformation. Glarus had two religions and two legislative assemblies, one representing each religious community, and Appenzell was split into two cantons according to religious lines. The Duchy of Savoy continued the war to reconquer Genève, but the city of Genève remained a Reformed enclave.

Catholicism was restored also in the Valais and in Solothurn. The Prince-Bishop of Basel regained some territories southwest of Basel, which turned to the Reformation in 1529. The Capuchins and the Jesuits, expressive of the Catholic Counter-Reformation, established schools and convents and largely favoured the process of re-catholicisation (Schaff 1882).

Hence following the application of the cuius regio eius religio principle, which aimed to establish a religious uniformity at least within each of the historically thirteen cantons, the Counter-Reformation was effective in reintroducing Catholicism also in parts of the reformed cantons. Furthermore, the initial effort of conversion to the Reformation and the subsequent re-catholicization determined the creation of a more mixed religious distribution in the dependent territories. Both phenomena favoured the formation of religious enclaves and minorities in most parts of the country. According to (Schaff 1882), Glarus, St. Gallen, Appenzell, Thurgau, and Aargau were nearly equally divided between the two denominations. Of the twenty-three subject towns and districts, only two became wholly Protestant, sixteen remained Catholic, and five were divided. In the Graubünden nearly two-thirds of the population adopted the Reformation.

Today the Reformed churches in Switzerland remain separate, cantonal units. The German churches are more in the Zwinglian tradition, the French more in the Calvinist tradition, but the differences are minor. All cantonal churches are federated in the Federation of Swiss Protestant Churches, which represents the common interests of its member churches on the national and international levels. Theologically the fundamental principles of the federation coincide with the cornerstones of Protestantism that we have already discussed: the primacy of the scriptures, salvation by faith alone, and universal priesthood.

The Federation of Swiss Protestant Churches reports five key tenets on its website:Footnote 35

  1. 1.

    solus Christus (By Christ alone): The love of Almighty God is evident in Jesus Christ, in his birth in poverty, his life, his preaching and healing, his crucifixion and resurrection. Jesus Christ opens the door to God, His and our Father in Heaven. He calls us to follow in His footsteps.

  2. 2.

    sola gratia (By grace alone) and sola fide (By faith alone): God’s salvation does not have to be earned; it is freely given to mankind (sola gratia). The only demand on us is that we accept it and receive the gift in faith (sola fide).

  3. 3.

    sola scriptura (By scripture alone): In questions of a Christian life and faith, the Reformed Churches are not guided by doctrines. They also have no authority to decree any binding directives. Their only guideline and source of knowledge are the scriptures of the Old and New Testaments.

  4. 4.

    soli Deo gloria (Glory to God alone): In praising God, we express the fact that we have Him to thank for everything. His mighty deeds and works are behind everything on earth. And so by praising God, we can move beyond ourselves and experience ourselves as part of a reality that transcends us.

  5. 5.

    The priesthood of all believers: everyone is received into the priesthood through baptism. The Reformed Churches do not differentiate between clergy and laymen but between general and official practice of work as a priest. Clergy are officially legitimised for this, meaning they are officially authorised to perform official duties for everything and everyone. Their office holds the specific task with which all who have been baptised are familiar: making the Gospel seen and heard throughout the world by word and deed.

Appendix 2: Placebo test

An important concern regarding the validity of our results is that the model may not pick up the effect of religious ethics but the effect of possibly differential characteristics of the territories where the religious groups reside, which could be more or less favourable to entrepreneurship. To address this concern we performed a placebo test which randomly reshuffles individual religious affiliation within each district, preserving the shares of each religious denomination, without thus altering the geographic distribution of majorities and minorities. As a result of reshuffling, any association between the reshuffled variable (religious denomination) and the rest of the dataset is random. On reshuffled data, interactions \(M_{idt}\times P_{idt}\) and \(m_{idt}\times P_{idt}\) were generated anew and model (1) was estimated to check whether a significant effect of Protestantism resulted. The presence of an effect would be an indication that the supposed influence of religious ethics on entrepreneurship is in fact due to confounders, and not to the respondents’ religion denomination. We repeated this operation 500 times. The effect of Protestantism was significantly different from zero only in 2 % of the repetitions, thus dismissing the concern that such an effect is due to non-religious factors.

Appendix 3: Additional tables

See Tables 11, 12, and 13.

Table 11 Religion and entrepreneurship—baseline model
Table 12 Alternative thresholds
Table 13 Proportions of minorities and majorities by geographical aggregation

Appendix 4: Additional figures

See Figs. 7, 8, 9 and 10.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Geographical distribution of Protestant minorities defined at the district level at alternative minority thresholds

Fig. 8
figure 8

Geographical distribution of Protestant minorities defined at the district level at alternative minority thresholds

Fig. 9
figure 9

Minority Protestant municipalities confining with majority Protestant areas, under alternative criteria

Fig. 10
figure 10

Minority Catholic municipalities confining with majority Catholic areas, under alternative criteria

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Nunziata, L., Rocco, L. A tale of minorities: evidence on religious ethics and entrepreneurship. J Econ Growth 21, 189–224 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-015-9123-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10887-015-9123-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation