Academia.eduAcademia.edu
1 China: three models of development by Michael Roberts 2 Abstract: 3 4 5 6 7 In the past 40 years, China's growth has been phenomenal. And since the global financial crisis and the Great Recession in the major capitalist economies, China has continued to close the output gap with the leading capitalist economies. Will China continue to catch up in the next 40 years or will it suffer the fate of the so-called 'middle income trap' experienced by other 'emerging' economies? 8 9 10 11 12 13 The paper considers three possible models of development as offered by: neoclassical growth theory; Keynesian-style forced investment; and a Marxian model based on the law of value and profitability. The neoclassical model highlights China’s comparative advantage of cheap and plentiful labour; the Keynesian model concentrates on the role of China’s high investment ratio; the Marxist model emphasises China’s exceptional restriction of the law of value in capitalist production: or 'socialism with Chinese characteristics'. 14 15 16 17 18 President Xi Jinping is now China’s most powerful leader since Mao Zedong. Like Mao, Xi now has his own ‘body of political thought’ carrying his name as added to the Communist party’s constitution after the 19th party congress at which Xi pledged to lead the world’s second largest economy into a “new era of international power and influence”. 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 In the past 40 years, China’s growth has been phenomenal. And since the global financial crisis and the Great Recession in the major capitalist economies, China has continued to close the output gap with the leading capitalist economies. On World Bank data, China’s industrial production in 2007 was only 60 % of the US level, whereas by 2011 it was 121 %. China’s industrial production has risen from being less than two-thirds of the US to overtaking the US by a substantial margin. In those six years China’s industrial output almost doubled while industrial production in the US, Europe and Japan did not even regain pre-crisis levels (Ross, 2013). 27 28 29 30 31 No country has ever grown so fast and been so large (with 19% of the world’s population) – only India, with 16 % of the world’s people, is close. Back in the early 1980s, three-quarters of the world’s people were better off than the average Chinese. Now only 31 % are. In 2010, 87 countries had a higher per capita GDP than China, but 83 were lower. This is an achievement without precedent. 32 33 34 35 36 37 Even if China’s average real economic growth were to slow from hereon to about 6 % a year instead of the double-digit expansion of the last decade, the gap with the G7 economies would continue to narrow. China’s working population has now peaked, but there are still hundreds of millions of rural workers and peasants to be incorporated into the industrial machine; and China is still sucking up as much of the world’s raw materials as it needs to sustain its expansion. 38 39 40 41 42 43 There is no other way to describe it: China is exceptional in the history of economic development over the last 250 years, surpassing even the earlier economic miracles of Asian economies like Japan or Korea. China’s share of global income has increased from less than 3 % in 1968 to nearly 15 % in 2016, with most of that increase occurring only after 2002. Indeed, the change in China’s share alone explains 87 % of the entire decline in the share of the advanced economies in the period 1980–2015. India is nowhere compared to China. Share of global GDP: China and India ($ market prices) 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 68 70 72 74 76 78 80 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 44 China India 45 Source: World Bank, Author’s calculations 46 47 48 As a result of this exceptional growth in output and incomes, over 800 million Chinese have been taken out of poverty, as defined by the World Bank, while other huge ‘developing’ economies have made little progress. Share of population living at below $5.5 a day. 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 49 50 Source: World Bank 51 52 53 54 What explains this miracle? There are several explanations that have been offered. This paper aims at analysing these explanations as though they were models of development. In this way, the explanations for China’s economic explosion and the prospects for the future are better drawn out. 55 The neoclassical ‘comparative advantage’ model 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 The consensus view is based on the neoclassical model of growth. World Bank economist Lin (2012) argues that China’s miracle is down to a switch in economic policy under Deng Xiaoping in the late 1970s away from what he calls a comparative advantage defying strategy (CAD) towards a comparative advantage following strategy (CAF). By this he means that China’s leaders realised that the bias in state intervention towards developing heavy industry at the expense of agriculture, or increasing capital inputs instead of using the plentiful supplies of cheap labour eventually created distortions in the prices of products, weakened agricultural prices and rural incomes relative to industry, kept consumption too low and generated over accumulation with low capital productivity. This led of a range of ‘unviable’ industries that could not compete in world markets. But under Deng, China took advantage of its real comparative advantage, the plentiful labour factor of production. Economic growth took off and China competed successfully in world markets through a powerful combination of foreign investment and cheap labour. 69 70 71 In this view, previously Mao had pursued a wrong strategy. Under Mao, lack of industrialization, especially large heavy industries that supported military strength, was seen as the root cause of China's then backwardness. China under Mao gave firms monopoly 72 73 74 75 76 power in heavy industry sectors and subsidized them with lower-priced inputs, often creating shortages. It allowed China to establish modern industries, test nuclear bombs in the 1960s and launch satellites in the 1970s. But labour-intensive sectors were repressed and yet that was where it held a comparative advantage. Thus, efficiency was low and growth prior to 1979 was driven mainly by increased inputs not productivity. 77 78 79 80 81 82 But under Deng, the argument goes, China embarked on a ‘dual-track system’, introducing reforms in some areas while maintaining the status-quo in others. Farmers were one of the first beneficiaries. They were allowed to own their land again (collective farms were broken up) and could set prices for selling their production that exceeded quota obligations sold to the state at fixed prices. Meanwhile, private enterprises, joint ventures and foreign investment into labour-intensive sectors were allowed. 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 According to Lin (2012), you can construct a ‘technological choice index’ based on the capital intensity of the manufacturing sector to measure a country’s choice of development strategy. This index can be used to measure how much the economy is distorted by a government. Given the development stage of a country, the higher this index is, the more an economy is distorted. Government had to collect heavy explicit taxes from the economic sectors that were generating a surplus and create direct financial subsidies for the non-viable industries. 90 91 92 93 94 95 Developing capital-intensive heavy industries was extremely costly and such industries could not hope to be viable in an open, free market economy. Thus, the government had to distort the economic institutions and nationalize resources, so as to sustain non-viable industry. According to Lin (2012) and others following this explanation, this was a flawed development strategy responsible for the increasing disparities in economic development among the provinces in China. 96 97 98 99 100 101 The priority industries under this strategy were inconsistent with the comparative advantage determined by the factor endowments in those provinces. Mao’s ‘leap-forward’ strategy retarded the functions of market, impeded capital accumulation and hindered technology and productivity progress in the provinces. Therefore, it was imperative to replace the comparative advantage-defying (CAD) strategy with a comparative advantage-following (CAF) strategy. 102 103 104 105 106 107 108 The key criterion for development must be ‘viability’ in the capitalist market. Lin (2012 p193) defined ‘viability’ as “if, without any external subsidies or protections, a normally managed enterprise is expected to earn a socially acceptable profit in a free, open, and competitive market, the enterprise is viable. Otherwise, the enterprise is non-viable.” If an enterprise in the long term does not expect to earn a socially acceptable profit, the enterprise should not be set up or should be driven out of the competitive market. This criterion was ignored in Mao’s CAD strategy, eventually generating a crisis of production. 109 110 111 But is this neoclassical model a convincing explanation for the take-off of China from the 1980s onwards? First, China’s economic growth prior to the Deng ‘reforms’ was not poor. As Lin (2012) himself admits, China’s real GDP increased at an annual average of 6.1 % 112 113 114 115 116 117 118 from 1952-78. According to the World Bank, China’s economic growth rate was 6.8% between 1970 and 1979, i.e., more than double that of the US during the same period. If we exclude the very first years of the People’s Republic from 1952 to 1962—i.e., between the completion of the unification of the continental territory and the period of the break with the Soviet Union—there was a recorded average of 8.2 % growth rate in 1963–78, reflecting very rapid growth even during the Cultural Revolution.(World Bank 2013a) The momentum of the Chinese economy was reached before Deng. 119 120 121 122 123 Second, is the law of comparative advantage useful as model for development? The law unrealistically assumes perfect mobility of labour. Furthermore, even defining comparative advantage is problematic. How do you measure the quality of labour or capital? For example, how can we decide whether the US is a capital-intensive or labour-intensive economy, without taking the quality of those inputs into account? 124 125 126 127 128 Third, we need market prices to measure comparative advantage. But supposed comparative advantages are endogenous to other economic factors. Comparative advantages are affected by trade. But gains from trade come from other mechanisms, including specialization, increasing returns, or the generation of commercial networks which lead to a later transmission of ideas and technologies. 129 130 131 132 133 134 Indeed, applying the law of comparative advantage does not mean a smooth equalisation of incomes and prices between regions within China or between economies through international trade, as Lin claims. Instead it can lead to crises and indeed it is crises that even out the differentials in costs and deliver industries or regions that are ‘unviable’. In other words, CAF could generate even more volatility and fluctuations in output and prices unless checked by CAD policy. 135 The Keynesian investment model 136 137 138 139 140 There is a Keynesian explanation as an alternative to the neoclassical market model. In this model, the key factor in China’s development was not a switch to a policy of ‘comparative advantage’ under Deng. In this model, it was not a switch to using cheap labour and allowing a rise in agricultural prices that allowed China to ‘take off’ but increased investment in machinery and technology i.e. greater capital inputs. 141 142 143 144 145 As total savings necessarily equals total investment, a rising proportion of national savings therefore necessarily means a rising proportion of investment. The Harrod-Domar (Harrod 1936, Domar 1941) growth model, later developed as the ‘endogenous growth model’, argues that growth depends on the quantity of capital input; more investment leads to capital accumulation, which generates economic growth. 146 147 148 149 150 In China, the model had relevance. Average growth rates of capital stock in China (excluding housing) rose 9.7 % a year 1952-78 and 10.9 % in the post-Deng period (World Bank 2013a). Including inventories, the rate was even higher pre-Deng. It is this sustained accumulation, enabled in particular by surplus transfers from rural areas, that explains the success of industrialization and, to a large extent, the robust rate of GDP growth. Investment to GDP (%) 1980-2018 48 43 38 33 28 23 18 2018 2016 2014 World ex China 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 EM ex Chi 2002 2000 1998 1996 Advanced economies 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 151 China 152 Source: IMF, Author’s calculations 153 154 155 156 157 158 But the Harrod-Domar model has a caveat. A rising proportion of the economy devoted to investment means any downturn in capital formation can have increasingly destabilising consequences. Thus it was necessary to revise China’s economic policy under Deng to reduce the impact of these destabilising influences. The Deng revolution was not to adopt CAF, as Lin claims, but to end administrative control of investment and replace it with Keynesianstyle stimulus and management that would boost private sector investment. 159 160 161 162 163 164 165 166 167 168 169 In this interpretation, the Chinese model of development, ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’, is in reality a radical version of Keynesianism according to Ross (Ross 2013). It is different to Keynesian policies in the US and Europe, where budget deficits have been utilised, low central bank interest rates have been pursued and some forms of quantitative easing, driving down long term interest rates through central bank purchases of debt have been applied. “In China, in contrast, relatively limited budget deficits have been combined with low interest rates, a state-owned banking system and a huge state investment programme. While the West’s economic recovery programme has been timid, China has pursued full blooded policies of the type recognisable from Keynes General Theory as well as its own ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics”. Ross argues that it was Deng’s lack of ideology or commitment to either a market or state-led economic model (Deng: "I don't care 170 171 if the cat is black or white, so long as it catches mice.") that was the reason for China’s economic success.1 172 The Marxist value model 173 174 175 176 177 178 179 180 181 182 183 184 185 186 187 A third model of development can be constructed from Marxist theory. Most Marxist analyses of China consider that China is now capitalist (Harvey 2005, Arrighi 2009, Panitch and Gindin 2013). But others reckon that the Chinese economic model has components clearly distinct from capitalism (Tiejun 2001, Amin 2013).2 In this Marxist model, China’s economic development is gauged from its ability to avoid the unstable impact of the law of value while also recognising its inexorable power. A Marxist model of China’s economic development does not start from looking at the comparative advantage of factors of production and or at the rate of savings or investment in an economy. Marxist theory starts from the law of value.3 The neoclassical alternative for economies that, like China (and the Soviet Union), had restricted the law of value to the barest minimum through central planning, state ownership of industry and collectivisation of agriculture was ‘shock therapy’. This solution was imposed in Russia and Eastern Europe i.e. a switch from a centrally planned economy, heavily industrialised and nationalised, into a market economy, with foreign investment and privatisation overnight with disastrous consequences. 188 189 190 191 192 193 194 Lin (2012) does not advocate ‘shock therapy’ for China, recognising the need for a ‘gradual’ switch from CAD to CAF policies, which he considers Deng did. But in the Marxist model, this means a gradual increase in the influence of the law of value into the Chinese economy; namely a bigger private sector, the accumulation of capital for profit, with prices determined by markets and not by a plan; and finally, the opening up of ‘free trade’, foreign investment, the ending of capital controls with a floating currency. This is what Lin and the World Bank regularly advocate for China in the next decade. 195 196 197 198 199 200 201 In contrast, the Marxist model recognises that it is not the absence of competition that produces imbalances and crises, with development alongside underdevelopment, wealth alongside poverty, employment alongside unemployment; it is competition itself. The problem with the neoclassical model is that there is confusion between the theory of comparative cost advantage and comparative factor advantage (Shaikh 2016). It is one thing to note that China has or had plentiful supplies of labour to develop (comparative factor advantage); it is another to conclude that not investing in heavy industry, but just using light “Because in the US and Europe, of course, it is held that the colour of the cat matters very much. Only the private sector coloured cat is good, the state sector coloured cat is bad. Therefore, even if the private sector cat is catching insufficient mice (ie the economy is in severe recession), the state sector cat must not be used to catch them. In China, both cats have been let loose – and therefore far more mice are caught.” (Ross 2014). 2 For a discussion of the different views, see Long, Herrera and Andréani (2018) 1 Marx’s law of value argues that, under capitalism, production is not to meet consumer needs alone but primarily to obtain profit, Value can only be created by the exertion of human labour and surplus value (or profit) thus emerges when capitalist producers sell goods and services on a market for commodities for a price that is higher than the costs of production. That is possible because the value created by labour power is more than the value paid to labour power. Human labour is exploited in this way. For more on Marx’s law of value, see Roberts (2018).. 3 202 203 204 205 industry and cheap labour can deliver economic growth and a comparative cost advantage in global markets. China’s exceptional growth would not have been achieved by relying just on the ‘comparative advantages’ of cheap labour and agriculture, combined with foreign investment. 206 207 208 209 210 211 212 213 214 215 216 217 218 219 220 Indeed, there is a growing contradiction between the expansion of industry and trade on world markets for China using its comparative factor advantages and the pressure of the law of value exerted through trade and foreign investment. The effects of foreign investment have a double impact. On the one hand, in the absence of foreign investment, China, like many other developing economies, would have had a structural trade deficit and foreign debt - or an import level restricted to the level supportable by a reduced export sector. However, the risk is that large-scale domestic industry would become dominated by foreign capital, side by side with backward industries in which local capital predominates. This might help the trade balance but would accelerate the devastation of local (capitalist and non-capitalist) production and act as a powerful blocking mechanism against the development of the indigenous forces of production. The destruction of native industry would displace more workers than can be newly employed in the relatively new hi-tech industries. This was the story of many new capitalist economies in the late 19th century onwards as developed by imperialist economies. It remains the story of most of Africa, much of Latin America and parts of Asia. 221 222 223 224 225 China remains the glaring exception. Why? Because as the Marxist model explains, the law of valuewhich operates in capitalist markets, foreign trade and investment was at first totally blocked and later controlled by a large state-owned sector, central planning and macro policy, as well as by restricted foreign ownership of new industries and controls on the flow of capital in and out of the country.4 226 227 228 229 230 231 As leading Chinese economist Yongding (2014) put it: “China has to maintain its capital controls in the foreseeable future. If China were to lose control over its cross-border capital flows, it could lead to panic and so capital outflows would turn into an avalanche and eventually bring down the whole financial system.” It was these very restrictions that enabled China to expand investment and technology, employ swathes of labour and generally avoid control of its destiny by multinational combines, up to now. 232 233 234 The neoclassical model now advocated for China by most mainstream economists, by many within the Chinese leadership and by outside international agencies deliberately fails to recognise the success of restricting the influence of the law of value in China’s development. 4 Joseph Stiglitz, Nobel Prize winner in economics, concluded, reviewing the history of financial crises: “Capital account liberalization was the single most important factor leading to the crisis. I have come to this conclusion not just by carefully looking at what happened in the [Asian] region, but by looking at what happened in the almost one hundred other economic crises of the last quarter century… capital account liberalization represents risk without a reward.” (Stiglitz 2017 p20). 235 236 237 238 The Keynesian analysis correctly looks at savings and investment as the key drivers of China’s development. But it also misses a key ingredient of economic development, the productivity of labour. And, in so far as there is a private sector in a developing economy and world markets, then profitability is the other key indicator. 239 240 241 242 243 244 245 246 The Marxist model argues that the level of productivity will decide economic growth because it reduces the cost of production and enables a developing nation to compete in world markets. But in a capitalist economy where the law of value and markets operate, there is a contradiction: profitability. In the Marxist model, there is a long-term inverse relationship between productivity and profitability (see Roberts 2018). As the former accelerates, the latter slows. Profitability comes into conflict with productivity growth in a capitalist economy and so will result in regular occurrences of crises in production. A developing economy needs to restrict this conflict to a minimum. 247 248 249 250 251 In a comparative study of models of economic growth, Vu Minh Khuong (Vu 2013) looked at productivity growth in developing economies. Productivity growth can be achieved by, either increased capital and labour inputs, or from raising the quality of existing capital and labour. Productivity accruing from ‘innovation’ is called total factor productivity (TFP) in mainstream economics (Solow 1954). 252 253 254 255 256 257 258 259 Vu (2013, p242)claims that his analysis shows that: “the secret of the Asian growth model lies not in achieving high TFP growth but in sustaining reasonable TFP growth”. According to Vu, capital investment inputs accounted for 54 % of the growth lead of developing Asian economies over the Western industrialized economies and for 62 % of developing Asia's lead over other developing economies. High capital investment was almost twice as important as productivity achieved from TFP increases in explaining Asia's growth lead over advanced economies. Indeed, as a country moves towards being an advanced economy, the role played by investment in its growth increases. 260 261 262 263 264 265 However, in a recent report, the IMF found that higher TFP explained 1.5 % points of the 1.75% points of higher average growth rate in developing economies in the 2000s prior to 2008 compared to the 1990s (IMF 2013). TFP growth turned positive in developing economies across all regions after declining in both Latin America and the Middle East and North Africa (MENA) region in the 1990s, although factor inputs still remained the main driver of output growth in developing economies throughout the 2000s. 266 267 268 269 270 271 So even if China’s rapid growth was originally founded on a very high ratio of capital investment, as well as on cheap labour, it may be a different story from hereon. Gross investment has averaged over 47 % of GDP since 2009. But real GDP growth has been slowing. So China's return on new investment (or the productivity of capital input) is declining. Back in 2006, before the global crisis, it took 2.9 units of investment to increase real GDP by 1 unit. In 2017, it took 7.2 units. (Brookings 2019) 272 273 274 In the Marxist model of capitalist development, productivity growth must be weighed against the contradiction of the law of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall (LTRPF) as capital is accumulated. In so far as China’s private capitalist sector increases its contribution to the 275 276 277 278 overall economy and the public sector’s role is reduced, then the profitability in the overall economy becomes relatively more important and the contradiction between productivity growth and profitability intensifies. Both the neoclassical and Keynesian models of development ignore this contradiction. 279 280 281 282 283 284 285 286 287 288 289 There have been various attempts to estimate the rate of profit in China ( Bai, Hsieh, Qian 2006, Yu and Feng 2006, Roberts 2009, Gaulard 2010, Maito 2012, Qu 2013, Herrera and Long 2014, Qi 2017). The empirical evidence reveals three phases of profitability in China. Between 1978-90, there was an upswing in profitability as production expanded from the Deng reforms and with the opening up of foreign trade. But from 1990 to the end of that decade, there was a fall, as over-investment gathered pace and other economies, particularly in the developing world, went through a series of crises (Mexico 1994, Asia 1997-8, Latin America 1998-01). The falling rate of profit then was accompanied by a slowing in the rate of GDP growth as the Marxist model would predict. However, from about 2001 onwards, there was a rise in profitability, which also saw a significant rise in the rate of economic growth (as the world too expanded at a credit-fuelled pace). Rate of profit in China 1978-2011 36% 34% China joins WTO 32% 30% Global slump 28% 26% Emerging market crises Deng period 24% 22% 20% 18% 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 290 291 Source: Chong et al (2006) and Qu et al. (2013), author’s calculations 292 293 294 295 296 All these studies find that the driving factor behind the secular decline in China’s rate of profit on capital was a rising organic composition of capital, which is the Marxist term for the ratio of capital input (constant capital in Marxist terms) over labour input (variable capital). Increased exploitation of labour helped to counteract this secular decline in profitability, particularly in the 2000s, but has not done so since the end of the Great Recession in 2009. 297 298 299 300 301 But Marx’s LTRPF and law of value have not operated with the same intensity and impact in China as in the major capitalist economies. The Great Recession and the subsequent Long Depression in the major capitalist economies confirm that. China’s real GDP growth and investment have outperformed all other G20 economies in the last ten years (including India, if its GDP is measured properly). 302 303 304 305 306 In China’s “socialism with Chinese characteristics”, there has been a significant expansion of privately-owned companies, both foreign and domestic over the last 30 years, with the establishment of a stock market and other financial institutions. Indeed, most observers, using official data, reckon that private sector enterprises constitute around 60-70% of GDP and assets now.(Xinhua 2018) 307 308 309 310 311 312 313 314 315 But this is misleading. Szamosszegi and Kyle, for the U.S.-China Economic and Security Review Commission analysed the influence of the state sector in China (2011). They defined the state sector as consisting of three main components: state-owned enterprises (SOEs) fully owned by the state through the State-owned Assets and Supervision and Administration Commission (SASAC); SOEs that are majority owners of enterprises that are not officially considered SOEs but are effectively controlled by their SOE owners; and entities, owned and controlled indirectly through SOE subsidiaries based inside and outside of China (SHEs). Urban collective enterprises and government-owned township and village enterprises (TVEs) also belong to the state sector but are not considered SOEs. 316 317 318 319 320 321 The authors commented: “A common mistake is to assume that any entity that is not an SOE belongs to the private sector. There is a state sector, which consists of SOEs, and a non-state sector, which consists of firms with other forms of ownership, including pure private ownership by domestic and foreign natural persons and mixed ownership entities in which SOEs are part owners and/or controlling. For the vast majority of these listed firms, the largest shareholders are SOEs.” (p10). 322 323 324 325 326 327 328 329 330 331 332 The Commission concluded that: “When data are analysed by sector, it becomes clear that SOEs and SHEs account for the majority of investments in most major sectors in the Chinese economy (p16). SOEs and SHEs were responsible for 40 percent of China’s GDP and 45 percent of non-agricultural GDP”.(p22) The Commission went on: “Given additional information on the prevalence of SOE ownership in China’s capital markets, anecdotal and observed data on the prevalence of SOE ownership among LLCs and other ownership categories, and the SOE role in round-tripped FDI, it is reasonable to conclude that by 2009 nearly half of China’s economic output could be attributable to either SOEs, SHEs, and other types of enterprises controlled by the SOEs indirectly. If the output of urban collective enterprises and the government-run proportion of TVEs are considered, the broadly defined state sector likely approximates 50 percent.”(p25) 333 334 335 336 More recently, a study by Hsieh and Song (2015) found that “the transformation of China's industrial sector that began in the late 1990s was not simply a resource shift from the public to the private sector. It also involved policy changes that transformed the remaining stateowned firms and created new ones.” (abstract). Instead of using the official definitions of the 337 338 339 340 341 342 343 344 state sector, the authors used another approach to identify state ownership that included ownership by ‘a legal person’. More than two-thirds of these companies were directly or indirectly controlled by SASAC but legally registered as private. When these private companies are redesignated as state-controlled, then SOEs still make up a substantial part of the national economy – roughly controlling 30 percent of the total secondary and tertiary assets, or over 50 percent of total industrial assets. The average size of SOEs is much bigger than their non-SOE peers, with average assets of the former equalling over 13 times of the latter. Hsieh and Song (2015), pp9-10). 345 346 347 348 349 350 351 WorldView (Stratfor 2018) found that “80-90 % of SOEs are concentrated in vital or highprofit industries such as finance, power, energy, telecommunications and defence manufacturing. And these enterprises — particularly the roughly 100 centrally administered SOEs — have grown much bigger. By 2017, the assets of these enterprises alone had reached 72 trillion yuan ($10.4 trillion), up more than tenfold from 2003 and almost equivalent to China's total GDP for that year. Since 2013, SOEs have received more than 60 percent of all new loans in China each year, peaking at 78 percent in 2016.” 352 353 354 355 356 357 358 359 360 361 In another survey by Milhaupt and Zheng from the Paulson Policy Memorandum (2016), of government or party affiliations of the founders or de facto controllers of China’s 100 largest private firms (by revenue) as ranked by the China National Association of Industry and Commerce, as well as China’s top ten private internet firms (by revenue), as ranked by the China Internet Association, 95 out of the top 100 private firms and eight out of the top ten internet firms had a founder or de facto controller who was currently or formerly a member of central or local political organizations such as People’s Congresses and People’s Political Consultative Conferences. One recent survey by the Central Organisation Department, the party’s personnel body, found that 68% of China’s private companies had party bodies by 2016, and 70% of foreign enterprises. (McGregor 2019) 362 363 364 365 366 367 368 369 For example, Huawei, China’s largest telecommunications equipment maker shares are held by its employees, in particular, the state-controlled trade union (although it is argued that the union has no say in corporate governance). Also, state-controlled industrial associations actively supervise the operations of private firms in their respective industries and have retained much, if not all, of the power exercised by their state predecessors. Private firms are prodded or even forced to participate in state-led industrial restructuring efforts. The right of corporate ownership must yield to the state’s plans for restructuring an industry. (Milhaupt and Zheng, 2015). 370 371 372 So it can be argued that even now much of employment and investment is still undertaken by publicly-owned companies or by institutions that are under the direction and control of the Communist party.5 The biggest part of China’s world-beating industry is not foreign-owned 5 Again, the employment share depends on what you consider is private sector in China. The usual statistics reckon that the state sector has only one-third of urban workforce. But decomposing the private sector into companies that have state minority stakes and depend on state funding, then ‘state sector’ employment will be higher. 373 374 375 376 377 378 multinationals, but Chinese state-owned enterprises. The major banks are state-owned and their lending and deposit policies are directed by the government (much to the chagrin of China’s central bank and other pro-capitalist elements). There is no free flow of foreign capital into and out of China. Capital controls are imposed and enforced; and the currency’s value is fixed in a narrow band to set economic targets (much to the annoyance of the US Congress). 379 380 381 382 383 384 385 386 The size and influence of the state sector in China is not replicated in any other economy. The IMF public sector database (IMF 2017) shows that public sector stock to GDP stands at 150 %; well ahead of that other Asian miracle of the past, Japan; and three times larger than in India or the US. Public sector assets are over three times larger than the private sector, while in every other major economy, private sector assets are larger. Public investment in China is annually 16 % of GDP compared to less than 4 % in the US or the UK. China is home to 109 corporations listed on the Fortune Global 500 - but only 15 % of those are privately owned. 387 China's public sector dominates: public sector stock to GDP; public/private asset ratio; public investment to GDP (%) 3.5 3.0 0.18 0.16 2.87 0.14 2.5 0.12 2.0 0.10 1.5 0.08 0.06 1.0 0.69 0.47 0.5 0.04 0.34 0.32 0.00 0.0 China 388 0.02 India Stock/GDP US Pub/Priv Russia UK Inv/GDP - RHS 389 390 Source: IMF Investment and Capital Stock database, Author’s calculations. Averages for period 2010-14 391 392 393 394 395 At the same time, the single party state machine infiltrates all levels of industry and activity in China. According to an analysisby Joseph Fang and others (Fang et al. 2013),claimed that “The Chinese Communist Party (CCP), by controlling the career advancement of all senior personnel in all regulatory agencies, all state-owned enterprises (SOEs), and virtually all major financial institutions state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and senior Party positions in all 396 397 but the smallest non-SOE enterprises, retains sole possession of Lenin’s Commanding Heights.” (p1). 398 399 400 401 402 403 404 405 406 407 The CCP Organization Department (CCP OD) managing all senior promotions throughout all major banks, regulators, government ministries and agencies, SOEs, and even many officially-designated non-SOE enterprises. The Party promotes people through banks, regulatory agencies, enterprises, governments, and Party organs, handling much of the national economy in one huge human resources management chart. In listed companies, each enterprise also has a Communist Party Committee, headed by a Communist Party Secretary. These advise the CEO on critical decisions and are kept informed by Party cells throughout the enterprise that also monitor the implementation of party policies. Indeed, the Party Secretary plays a leading role in major decisions and can overrule or bypass the CEO and board if necessary. 408 409 410 411 412 413 414 Companies including Alibaba already have communist cells embedded in their operations and top executives spend much of their time dealing with government officials on policy and other issues. Fraser Howie, co-author of Red Capitalism (2011), said the move highlighted how ostensibly private companies are “state overseen enterprises”. “All Chinese corporates are effectively either state owned enterprises or state overseen enterprises,” he said. “And there seems to be no move to get away from that and indeed more and more effort to make it very clear the private sector are beholden to the Party.”6 415 The future of China’s development 416 417 418 419 420 But what of the future? Let us consider what the three models suggest? If Lin and others of the neoclassical CAF school are correct, then China needs drastic restructuring of its economic model. The argument goes that China is now a ‘middle-income’ (capitalist) economy and unless it allows the market to rule, it will not close the gap in productivity and income per head with the advanced, older capitalist economies. 421 422 423 424 425 426 427 The argument of the Sinology ‘experts’ of mainstream economics is that only ‘turning to the market’ will enable China to escape from the so-called ‘middle income trap’.7 They mean that, to begin with, ‘emerging economies’ can grow fast with big capital investment and exports using cheap labour and new technology – the Chinese model. But less than a fifth of the 180 countries in the world have made it to being advanced economies. Of the 101 countries that were “middle-income” in 1960, only 13 had managed to break from the pack to become advanced economies by 2008 (World Bank 2013a). 6 As quoted in the Financial Times, 23 September, 2019, https://www.ft.com/content/055a1864-ddd3-11e9b112-9624ec9edc59 7 Two prominent and recent narratives along these lines are by Nicholas Lardy, The state strikes back: the end of economic reform in China? (2019), https://www.piie.com/bookstore/state-strikes-back-end-economic-reformchina and George Magnus, with Red Flags: Why Xi’s China is in Jeopardy (2018, Yale University Press (2018)https://georgemagnus.com/ 428 429 430 431 432 433 434 435 436 One reason why countries get stuck in this “middle-income trap” is that they reach what is known as the ‘Lewis Point’, after the left economist of the 1950s, Arthur Lewis (Lewis 1954). Put simply, this is the point at which a developing country stops being able to achieve rapid growth relatively easily, by taking rural workers doing unproductive farm labour and putting them to work in factories and cities instead. At a certain point, this ‘reserve army of labour’ is exhausted, urban wages rise, incomes reach a certain level and a ‘middle-class’ emerges. Distorting Lewis’ theory, mainstream economics asserts that then there must be a switch to boosting domestic consumption that a state-led economy cannot do. So the cry is “liberalise with free trade and capital – that’s the only way to move on” (McGregor 2010). 437 438 439 440 441 442 A World Bank report (World Bank 2013b), taking up Lin’s and other neoclassical views and published in conjunction with China’s advisory body, the Development Research Center of China’s State Council, argued that there would be an economic crisis in China unless staterun firms were scaled back. The report said the answer was to set up ‘asset-management firms’ to sell off state industries, overhaul local government finances and promote ‘competition and entrepreneurship’. 443 444 445 446 447 But is this scenario of the ‘middle-income’ trap really due to the loss of ‘comparative advantage’ in cheap labour, Lewis-point style? Or is it due to the failure of developing capitalist economies to raise productivity and sustain investment in technology and human capital in the face of cycles of falling profitability and global crises, often engendered in the mature capitalist economies and thus outside the control of individual national economies? 448 449 450 451 452 It is no accident that only two large developing capitalist economies have succeeded in becoming part of the rich capitalist club in the last 50 years. Measured in GDP per capita and starting at $3000 per head (PPP real) 40 years ago, Taiwan and Korea now have per capita GDPs over $25,000. In the same period, no other Asian (large) tiger or Latin American economy has risen above $13,000 - still within the World Bank’s middle income range. 453 454 455 456 457 458 Taiwan was a special client state of the US and also benefited hugely from China’s own expansion and from Japanese trade. Korea also had a special trade agreement with US. Both economies had large state holding companies, military regimes that restricted ‘free markets’ and were oriented to investment in heavy industry and technology – not the neoclassical model. Interestingly, at its current stage in this process, China’s per capita GDP is higher and growing much faster than even Taiwan and Korea were at their take-offs. 459 460 461 462 463 464 465 466 In a recent monumental study of the ‘Asian economic miracle’, called ironically, Reda Cherif and Fuad Hasanov for the IMF concluded that “high sustained growth” was the result of what it called “True Industrial Policy” (TIP) where “the state set ambitious goals, managed to adapt fast, and imposed accountability for its support to industries and firms. We argue that TIP was based on the state intervention to facilitate the move of domestic firms into sophisticated sectors beyond the existing comparative advantage.” (p63)The IMF economists’ conclusion directly contradicts the neoclassical model of comparative advantage that promotes “import substitution industrialization strategies, prevalent until the late 1980s 467 468 among developing economies” because “that led to inefficiencies, lack of innovation, and persistent dependence on key imported inputs.”(p63) (Cherif and Hasanov, IMF 2019). 469 470 471 472 473 The development challenge ahead for China is not ‘rebalancing’ the economy away from investment towards consumption, but to raise productivity growth through innovation in a new period of an ageing and falling working population. Growth comes either from increasing capital and labour inputs or from higher productivity. And it is in the latter that China must deliver. In this area, China has a long way to go, but it is catching up. Ratio of productivity of labour China-US (%) 25 20 15 10 5 0 2016 2013 2010 2007 2004 2001 1998 1995 1992 1989 1986 1983 1980 1977 1974 1971 1968 1965 1962 1959 1956 1953 1950 474 475 Source: OECD, World Bank, Author’s calculations 476 477 478 479 480 Almost half of China’s gross domestic product (GDP) growth since 1978 was from capital deepening, about a third was from productivity, measured by total factor productivity (TFP), and the rest was from an expanding labour force and investments in human capital (World Bank 2019). Consistent with the recent slowdown of TFP growth, China’s labour productivity growth has also been declining. 481 482 483 484 485 486 China’s average productivity level is just 20 % of the US. And the US economy remains highly productive even compared to other advanced economies. While the US share of global research and development (R&D) has declined, in part due to a rapid increase in China’s share, the US remains the global R&D leader, accounting for nearly 30 % of the world total. Data on patents granted—either total or specifically abroad—show that the US share has held roughly steady at around 20 %. China’s share of total patents granted has risen very rapidly 487 488 over the last decade to over 20 %, but most patents granted to Chinese innovators have come from the domestic patent office, with far fewer granted abroad.8 489 490 491 492 493 494 495 496 497 Knowledge and technology intensive (KTI) industries contribute 38 % of US GDP, the highest of any major economy. But China is not far behind at 35 %, unusually high for a developing economy. While the US is the largest producer of high-tech goods, its share of world exports has shrunk considerably while China’s share has grown. China’s R&D intensity, measured by R&D spending as a percentage of GDP, was 2.1 % of GDP versus 2.8 % for the US. Indeed, China has seen an almost 160 % increase in intellectual property receipts from the world in the past decade, compared with an 11 % increase for the US over the same time frame, which indicates China’s increased knowledge diffusion throughout the world (Santacreu and Makenzie, 2019). 498 499 500 501 502 China’s recent policies have focused on fostering discovery and new technologies. Investments in new technologies as China remains, on average, quite distant from the global technology frontier and thus has substantial remaining potential for catch-up). According to the World Bank, China could double its GDP simply by catching up to OECD countries in its TFP. (World Bank 2012). 503 504 505 506 507 The global innovation index—developed by the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), INSEAD, and Cornell University—shows that China’s innovation capacity has been improving steadily. China is moving up in cross-country rankings, from 29 in 2011 to 17 in 2018, and it is the highest-ranking middle-income country and the first middle-income country to join the 20 most innovative. (WIPO 2019) 508 509 510 511 512 513 514 515 516 The biggest threat to US hegemony in R&D and innovation technology is Beijing’s plan to replicate foreign technologies and foster national champions that can take them global. A program launched in 2015, called ‘Made in China 2025’, aims to make the country competitive within a decade in ten industries, including aircraft, new energy vehicles, and biotechnology. China, under Xi, aims not just to be the manufacturing centre of the global economy but also to take a lead in innovation and technology that will rival that of the US and other advanced capitalist economies within a generation. Beijing aims to boost the share of domestically made robots to more than 50 % of total sales by 2020, from 31 % in 2018. (China Briefing 2018) 517 518 519 520 521 522 523 Under Xi, China has also redoubled efforts to build its own semiconductor industry. The country buys about 59 % of the chips sold around the world, but in-country manufacturers account for only 16 % of the industry’s global sales revenue, according to PwC (Bloomberg 2018). To rectify that, Made in China 2025 earmarks $150 billion in spending over ten years. These moves by China are at the heart of the trade war hotting up with the US. US Commerce Secretary Wilbur Ross has described the Made in China plan as an “attack” on “American genius.” (Woodward 2018). Then there is China’s Belt and Road Initiative, a 8 Goldman Sachs Global Investment Research, April 2018 524 525 global development strategy involving infrastructure development and investments in 152 countries and international organizations.9 526 527 528 529 530 531 China’s exports have soared in dollar terms—17 percent annually in the past two decades— and its export market shares for both gross trade and added value have risen significantly. The contribution of China’s exports to its growth has been falling with the slowdown in global trade since the global financial crisis of 2008, but its share of global trade has been rising. China’s share of global exports of goods increased from only 3.9 percent in 2000 to 14.6 percent in 2017. (World Trade Organization 2019). 532 533 534 535 536 537 538 539 540 Foreign investments have been critical for China’s export growth and international competitiveness. Foreign-invested enterprises contributed to nearly half of China’s imports and exports, one-fourth of industrial output, and one-fifth of tax revenue in 2017. China was the second-largest destination for FDI in the world, after the United States, in 2018. According to the World Investment Report 2017 (UNCTAD 2017), multinational firms consider China the second-most-preferred destination for cross-border investment in the world. China has evolved from being a net importer of FDI to a net exporter in 2016. Despite experiencing a sharp decline in 2017, China’s outbound investments were the third-largest in the world. China’s FDI and ODI still have room to grow. 541 542 543 544 545 546 547 548 China’s drive under Xi for technological equality and higher productivity through innovation does not follow the neoclassical school development model that is ‘consumption-led’ and dominated by markets. But the supporters of this model dominate the development discussion. The neoclassical model remains full of holes. It is not true that the Chinese economy has restricted consumption. Consumption may have fallen as a share of GDP during the fast pace of investment expansion and urbanisation of the last 40 years, but real consumption in China has been growing at 8.8% annually for over two decades — the highest of any major economy. 10 549 550 551 552 553 554 555 556 557 558 559 What has happened with the relative ‘liberalisation’ of the economy, the expansion of the private sector, global trade and investment is the encroachment of the law of value into new areas of the economy and with it, a huge rise in the inequality of wealth and income. China’s gini coefficient, an index of income inequality, according to Xie and Zhou (2014) rose from 0.30 in 1978, when the Communist Party began to open the economy to market forces, to 0.49by 2008 . This rise was partly the result of the urbanisation of the economy as rural peasants move to the cities. Urban wages in the sweatshops and factories are increasingly leaving peasant incomes behind (not that those urban wages are anything to write home about when workers assembling Apple i-pads are paid under $2 an hour). But it is also partly the result of the elite controlling the levers of power, while allowing some Chinese billionaires to flourish. Urbanisation has slowed since the Great Recession (from a peak annual rate of “Belt" refers to the overland routes for road and rail transportation, called "the Silk Road Economic Belt"; whereas "Road" refers to the sea routes, or the 21st Century Maritime Silk Road. 10 Author’s calculation from World Bank Development Indicators 1995-2018 9 560 561 3.75% before to just 1.3% after11), and so has economic growth – and from 2008, China’s gini inequality index fell back a little, if still at a high level.12 China: gini coefficient ratio ( 100 = total inequality; 1 = total equality) 49.5 49.0 49.1 49.0 48.7 48.5 48.1 48.0 48.0 47.7 47.4 47.3 47.5 46.9 47.0 46.5 46.5 46.7 46.2 46.0 45.5 45.0 44.5 06 562 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 563 Source: China National Bureau of Statistics 564 565 566 567 568 569 570 571 572 573 The debate within the leadership will continue about which way to take China: towards a full market economy open to the winds of global capitalism or to stay as they are. The Chinese Communist party’s Third Plenum of the 18th Congress in 2013 discussed what to do about China over the following five to ten years. The third plenum did not really commit to anything like ‘free market’ capitalism. There was no change in the general philosophy of ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’ and thus the maintenance of the dominance of the state sector. Also, there would be no move towards ‘democracy’ or control of even local legal systems and decisions by the people. On the contrary, the leadership has set up even more repressive state security services to monitor and control the population and curb any dissidence.13 574 575 576 577 578 This trade and technology trade war that is intensifying with the US will set the parameters for China’s development over the next decades. China’s development over the last 40 years through state-directed and controlled planning and enterprises, combined with an expansion of a private sector has been unique in its formation. The next stage is one where the development model must be directed towards productivity growth in an environment where 11 Urban population as percentage of total population, China Statistical Yearbook, 2017 China National Statistical Bureau 13 "China issues detailed reform roadmap". Xinhua News Agency (15 November 2013 12 579 580 581 the profitability of capital remains a serious obstacle. And now there is added risk of growing economic and political confrontation with the hegemonic power of the US which seeks to clip the wings of China’s crane. 582 Bibliography 583 Amin S, “China 2013,”Monthly Review 64, no. 10, March 2013: 14–33 584 Arrighi G, Adam Smith in Beijing (London: Verso, 2009). 585 586 587 Bloomberg (2018), China Invites Foreign Cash to Build a World-Class Chip Industry, https://www.industryweek.com/economy/china-invites-foreign-cash-build-world-class-chipindustry 588 589 590 Brookings, Joyless growth in China, India and the United States, 22 January 2019, https://www.brookings.edu/blog/future-development/2019/01/22/joyless-growth-in-chinaindia-and-the-united-states/ 591 592 593 Cao, J., Ho, M. S., Jorgenson, D. W., Ren, R., Sun, L., & Yue, S. (2009, July). 'Industrial and Aggregate Measures of Productivity Growth in China, 1982-2000'. The Review of Income and Wealth, 485-513. 594 595 China Briefing (2018) The Robotics Industry in China, https://www.chinabriefing.com/news/chinas-robot-industry/ 596 597 598 Cowen Tyler, (2013) Marginal Revolution: http://marginalrevolution.com/marginalrevolution/2013/09/why-the-theory-of-comparativeadvantage-is-overrated.html#sthash.dFYLPMgB.dpuf 599 600 601 Deng, X. (13 October 1987). We Are Undertaking an Entirely New Endeavour. In Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping Vol. 3 1982-1992 (1994 ed., pp. 249-252). Beijing: Foreign Language Publishers. 602 603 Deng, X. (21 August 1985). Two Kinds of Comments About China's Reform. In Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping Vol. 3 1982-1992 (1994 ed., pp. 138-9). Foreign Languages Press. 604 605 606 Deng, X. (28 August 1985). Reform is the only way for China to develop its productive forces. In X. Deng, Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping 1982-1992 (1994 ed., pp. 140-143). Beijing: Foreign Languages Press. 607 608 Domar, Evsey (1946). "Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and Employment". Econometrica. 14 (2): 137–147. 609 610 Fan Joseph and Morck Randall, editors, Capitalizing China, University of Chicago Press, NBER 2013, https://www.nber.org/books/morc10-1 611 612 Gaulard Mylene (2010), in World in Crisis (2018), co=ed Carchedi G and Roberts M (2018), Haymarket Books, Chicago. http://gesd.free.fr/m6gaulard.pdf. 613 Gau Xu, State-owned enterprises in China: How big are they? (2010) 614 615 Harrod, Roy F. (1939). "An Essay in Dynamic Theory". The Economic Journal. 49 (193): 14–33. 616 Harvey, D, A Brief History of Neoliberalism (New York: Oxford University Press, 2005). 617 618 Herrera Remy and Long Zhiming, Capital Accumulation, Profit Rates and Cycles in China from 1952 to 2014, (2014, Journal of Innovation, Economics and Management, 2 No 23. 619 620 Hongbin, Qu, Julia Wang & Sun Junwel. 2013. China inside out. return on capital: perception vs reality, HSBC Global Research, Hong Kong. 621 622 Howie, Fraser, Walter Carl, Red Capitalism: The Fragile Financial Foundation of China's Extraordinary Rise (2011) 623 624 Hsieh Chang and Song Zheng 2015, Grasp the Large, Let Go of the Small: The Transformation of the State Sector in China (NBER Working Paper No. 21006). 625 626 627 628 Hubbard Paul, Reconciling China’s official statistics on state ownership and control, Crawford School of Public Policy, Australian National University (2012). http://www.eaber.org/system/tdf/documents/EABER%20Working%20Paper%20120%20Hub bard.pdf?file=1&type=node&id=25575&force= 629 630 631 IMF 2017, Estimating the stock of public capital in 170 countries, https://www.imf.org/external/np/fad/publicinvestment/pdf/csupdate_jan17.pdf, Investment and Capital Stock Dataset, 1960-2015 632 633 IMF: Cherif Reda, Hasanov Fuad (2019), The Return of the Policy That Shall Not Be Named: Principles of Industrial Policy, IMF Working paper March 2019. 634 635 Jorgenson, D. W. (2009). 'Introduction'. In D. W. Jorgenson (Ed.), The Economics of Productivity (pp. ix-xxviii). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. 636 637 Jorgenson, D. W., Gollop, F. M., & Fraumeni, B. M. (1987). Productivity and US Economic Growth. New York 638 639 Lardy, N. R. (1993). Foreign Trade and Economic Reform in China 1978-1990. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. 640 641 Lardy N R, The state strikes back: the end of economic reform in china? (2019), https://www.piie.com/bookstore/state-strikes-back-end-economic-reform-china 642 643 Lewis, W. Arthur (1954). “Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labor,” Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 22, pp. 139-91. 644 645 Lin, J. Y. (2012). Demystifying the Chinese Economy. Cambridge UK: Cambridge University Press. 646 647 648 Long Z and Herrera R (2014), “Capital Accumulation, Profit Rates and Cycles in China from 1952 to 2014: Lessons from the Evolution of Chinese Industry,” Journal of Innovation Economics & Management 23: 2017, 59–82. 649 650 651 652 Long Z, Herrera R and Andréani T, On the Nature of the Chinese Economic System, Monthly Review, October 2018, https://monthlyreview.org/2018/10/01/on-the-nature-of-the-chineseeconomic-system/#en2Magnus George, Red Flags: Why Xi’s China is in Jeopardy (2018, Yale University Press (2018), https://georgemagnus.com/ 653 Maito Esteban, in World in Crisis (2018) op cit, http://gesd.free.fr/maito14.pdf 654 655 656 657 McGregor James (2010), China’s Drive for 'Indigenous Innovation' - A Web of Industrial Policies, US Chamber of Commerce, https://www.uschamber.com/report/china%E2%80%99s-drive-indigenous-innovation-webindustrial-policies 658 659 660 McGregor Richard, How the state runs business in China, Guardian, July 2019, https://www.theguardian.com/world/2019/jul/25/china-business-xi-jinping-communist-partystate-private-enterprise-huawei 661 662 663 Milhaupt Curtis, Zheng Wentong, Beyond Ownership: State Capitalism and the Chinese Firm, Georgetown Law Journal, 2015, https://ecgi.global/sites/default/files/working_papers/documents/SSRN-id2413019.pdf 664 665 Panitch L and Gindin S, “The Integration of China into Global Capitalism,” International Critical 666 667 Paulson Institute, (2017).http://www.paulsoninstitute.org/wpcontent/uploads/2017/01/PPM_SOE-Ownership_Milhaupt-and-Zheng_English_R.pdf 668 669 Qia Hua (2017) The historical peak of the rate of surplus value and the “new normal” of the Chinese economy: a political economy analysis, Renmin University 670 Roberts M, The Great Recession (2009), Lulu. 671 Roberts M. Marx 200 – a review of Marx’s economics 200 years since his birth (2018), Lulu. 672 673 674 Ross John, (2013) Key Trends in Globalisation: http://ablog.typepad.com/keytrendsinglobalisation/2013/09/china-has-overtaken-theus.html). 675 676 Ross John, (2014) Den Xiaoping and John Maynard Keynes, Learning from China, https://www.learningfromchina.net/deng-xiaoping-john-maynard-keynes/ 677 678 Santacreu, Ana Maria and Zhu, Heting (2018). Domestic Innovation and International Technology Diffusion as Sources of Comparative Advantage, Federal Reserve Bank of St. 679 680 681 682 Santancreu Anna Maria and Peake Makenzie, China’s Innovation and Global Technology Diffusion, Federal Reserve Bank St Louis, March 2019, https://files.stlouisfed.org/files/htdocs/publications/economic-synopses/2019/03/08/chinasinnovation-and-global-technology-diffusion.pdf 683 Shaikh Anwar, (2016), Capitalism, competition, conflict and crises, Oxford University Press Thought 3, no. 2 (2013): 146–58. 684 685 Solow, R. M. (1957). ‘Technical change and the Aggregate Production Function'. Review of Economics and Statistics (3), 312-320. 686 687 688 Stiglitz Joseph (2017), Globalization and its Discontents Revisited, W. W. Norton & CompanyTiejun Wen, “Centenary reflections on the ‘three dimensional problem’ of rural 689 690 691 US-China Commission on State-owned enterprises and state capitalism (2015). http://sites.utexas.edu/chinaecon/files/2015/06/US-China-Commission_State-OwnedEnterprises-and-State-Capitalism.pdf 692 693 Vu, K. M. (2013). The Dynamics of Economic Growth - Policy Insights from Comparative Analyses in Asia. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, M.A., US: Edward Elgar. 694 Woodward Jude, (2017), The US vs China: Asia's New Cold War? (Geopolitical Economy) 695 696 World Bank (2012), China 2030: Building a Modern, Harmonious, and Creative HighIncome Society. 697 698 World Bank (2013a), The World Bank in Middle Income Countries, https://www.worldbank.org/en/country/mic/overview 699 700 World Bank (2013b), China 2030: Building a Modern, Harmonious, and Creative Society; https://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/China-2030-complete.pdf 701 702 World Bank (2019), Innovative China: New Drivers of Growth World Bank Group Development Research Center of the State Council, the People’s Republic of China 703 704 World Trade Organization, World Trade Statistical Review 2019, https://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/wts2019_e/wts2019chapter05_e.pdf 705 706 World Intellectual Property Organisation (WIPO) Global Innovation Index 2019, https://www.wipo.int/pressroom/en/articles/2019/article_0008.html 707 708 World View, Strafor, 2018, https://worldview.stratfor.com/article/state-owned-enterprisesare-hard-habit-china-doesnt-want-break 709 710 711 Xie Yu and Zhou Xiang, Income inequality in today’s China (2014), Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America (PNAS), https://www.pnas.org/content/111/19/6928 712 Xinhua, 2018 http://www.xinhuanet.com/english/2018-03/06/c_137020127.htm 713 714 715 Yongding Yu, (2014), Don’t Bet On A Chinese Financial Meltdown, At Least For Now, China-US Focus 9 April, https://www.chinausfocus.com/finance-economy/dont-bet-on-achinese-financial-meltdown-at-least-for-now 716 717 Zheng, J., Bigsten, A., & Hu, A. (2009). 'Can China's Growth Be Sustained? A Productivity Perspective'. World Development, 37(4), 874-888. China,” Inter-Asia Cultural Studies 2, no. 2 (2001): 287–95.