Skip to main content
Log in

The rise of modern taxation: A new comprehensive dataset of tax introductions worldwide

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article describes the new Tax Introduction Dataset (TID). Listing the year and the mode of the first permanent introduction of six major taxes (inheritance tax, personal income tax, corporate income tax, social security contributions, general sales tax and value added tax) in 220 countries, 1750–2018, TID is the most comprehensive dataset of its kind. The comprehensiveness of our measure is of critical value to empirical work on the causes of tax innovation and its consequences for state, society and economy. In this paper, we explain the selection of our tax sample and the structure of the dataset, descriptively map temporal and regional patterns of tax introductions around the world, and draw on TID to investigate associations between tax introductions and economic development, war, and democratization.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Obviously, temporary emergency taxes may turn into permanent taxes. The relevant criteria for TID is the factual permanence of a tax. See the code book for further detail (Genschel and Seelkopf 2019). The codebook, the dataset as well as further supplementary material is available on the Review of International Organizations’ webpage. Please visit https://www.tid.seelkopf.eu for the most recent data version.

  2. 25 countries no longer exist. They include historical states that have since been enveloped by larger states, such as the Republic of Vietnam or East Germany, as well as large historical states that have since fragmented, such as Great Colombia, Czechoslovakia and Yugoslavia.

  3. Note that small UN member states such as Andorra or Antigua and Barbuda are included in COW/TID even though they have populations substantially smaller than 500.000. This is important for tax research because many tax havens are very small (Genschel et al. 2016).

  4. For more information on the TID country list and its differences to the COW list, please consult the TID codebook (Genschel and Seelkopf 2019).

  5. In addition, we also collected information on the tax rate in the year of introduction as well as a dummy for subnational tax introduction: was the national introduction of a tax preceded by an introduction of the same tax at the subnational level? The data on these two variables are not exhaustive, hence we don’t present them here.

  6. For further information on coding rules for missings and never introduced see the code book (Genschel and Seelkopf 2019). The current version of the dataset includes just around 4% (57 cases) of fully missing cases. For another 7% we know that the tax was introduced, but have no information on the mode and/or the year. For a very small minority of cases (10 or 0.8%) we know the mode but not the year of introduction, implying that we have full information for 1169 or 88% of our cases.

  7. For more information on our search strategy, see the Codebook (Genschel and Seelkopf 2019).

  8. The Financing the State dataset covering 31 countries from the early nineteenth century is probably the best source available (Andersson and Brambor 2018).

  9. Sometimes, SSCs are charged on other forms of income as well. For instance, the SSC system adopted in Chile in 1924 included mandatory contribution for self-employed persons with a weekly turnover of up to five thousand pesos (Chile 1924 art. 1–11).

  10. Withholding at source means that income tax is remitted by the payer of income rather than the income-recipient, i.e. the employer remits tax on behalf of its employees (before paying out net-wages), the bank remits tax on behalf of savers (before paying out net-interest earnings) (Slemrod 2007).

  11. Low income caps tend to increase the regressivity of SSCs, high caps tend to lower it (Ganghof 2007, 1075).

  12. It is suggestive of the perceived success that an existing VAT has only ever been removed in six cases —Vietnam (in the 1970s), Grenada (introduced 1986, dismantled shortly thereafter), Ghana (introduced March 1995, removed 2 months later), Malta (introduced 1995, removed 1997), Belize (introduced 1996, removed 1999) and British Columbia (introduced 2010, removed 2011). However, in all cases, except for British Colombia, the tax has since been reintroduced: Ghana in 1998, Malta and Vietnam in 1999, Belize in 2006 and Grenada in 2010 (International Tax Dialogue 2013, 17; Financial Tribune 2017).

  13. Is the differences in diffusion speed ‘real’ or is it driven by changes in the composition of the country sample (i.e. by a secular increase in the number of tax jurisdictions)? We address this question below.

  14. Note, however, that the first modern tax ever to be introduced was a SSC: In 1758 the German principality of Baden, an independent state until German unification in 1871, introduced a contribution-based survivor pension system for its civil servants.

  15. We have searched quite extensively for such a dataset, but could not find a solution. Building such a dataset ourselves would require at least as much effort to create than TID. Hence, we decided to rely on the COW state list, one of the most commonly used political science databases, and extend it wherever necessary (see Genschel and Seelkopf 2019).

  16. British India introduced the CIT already in 1886, Britain only in 1965.

  17. In a nutshell, the cost diseases argument goes like this: government is labor-intensive; labor-intensive industries tend to have lower productivity gains than more capital-intensive businesses; as a consequence, the government has to spend more on the provision of labor-intensive public services in order to keep the ratio of these services constant with the rising output of income and wealth by the more capital-intensive private sector.

  18. We define the risk-of-introduction year of a tax as 10 years prior to its first introduction worldwide. As a consequence, the analysis of the following three taxes does not start 1816 but at a later date: CIT (1863–2015), GST (1894–2015), VAT (1957–2015). PIT, INH and SSCs already existed by 1816.

  19. Gapminder merges data from various sources to arrive at a comprehensive dataset that covers both colonies and independent states from 1800 until today. More information on the variable creation can be found here: https://www.gapminder.org/data/documentation/gd001/

  20. We follow the convention in the literature and count conflicts with more than 1000 battle death as major wars. As a robustness check, we also include a dummy that takes on the value 1 for conflict years and observations 10 years before/after a conflict took place.

  21. These are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and the United States.

  22. RoW includes all sovereign countries, for which data is available, minus the OECD-18.

  23. There are only three exceptional cases, in which the same factor is associated with the same tax introduction in both country groups. These are modernization in the case of SSC introduction, as well as war and democratization in the case of INH introduction.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Why did the west extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4), 1167–1199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 938–963.

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge University Press.

  • Aidt, T. S., & Jensen, P. S. (2009a). Tax structure, size of government, and the extension of the voting franchise in Western Europe, 1860–1938. International Tax and Public Finance, 16(3), 362–394.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., & Jensen, P. S. (2009b). The taxman tools up: An event history study of the introduction of the personal income tax. Journal of Public Economics, 93(1–2), 160–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (1997). On the number and size of nations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1027–1056.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alm, J., Jackson, B. R., & McKee, M. (1993). Fiscal exchange, collective decision institutions, and tax compliance. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 22(3), 285–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, P. (2017). “Taxation in non-democratic states: Investments vs. redistribution.” In: Pathways to modern taxation - European University Institute. Florence.

  • Andersson, P., and Brambor, T. (2018). “Financing the state - central government revenues, 1800–2012 (dataset),” 2018. www.reformcapacity.org/data. Accessed 25 Feb 2018.

  • Appel, H., & Orenstein, M. A. (2013). Ideas versus resources explaining the flat tax and pension privatization revolutions in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. Comparative Political Studies, 46(2), 123–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ardant, G. (1975). Financial policy and economic infrastructure of modern states and nations. The Formation of National States in Western Europe, 164, 218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartels, L. M. (2005). Homer gets a tax cut: Inequality and public policy in the American mind. Perspectives on Politics, 3(1), 15–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bastiaens, I., & Rudra, N. (2016). Trade liberalization and the challenges of revenue mobilization: Can international financial institutions make a difference? Review of International Political Economy, 23(2), 261–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J. (1993). Health care, education and the cost disease: A looming crisis for public choice. Public Choice, 77(1), 17–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N., Katz, J. N., & Tucker, R. (1998). Taking time seriously: Time-series-cross-section analysis with a binary dependent variable. American Journal of Political Science, 42(4), 1260–1288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beramendi, P., & Rueda, D. (2007). Social democracy constrained: Indirect taxation in industrialized democracies. British Journal of Political Science, 37(4), 619–641.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Persson, T. (2009). The origins of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics. The American Economic Review, 99(4), 1218–1244.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., and Persson, T. (2011). Pillars of prosperity: The political economics of development clusters. Princeton University Press.

  • Besley, T., and Persson, T. (2013). “Taxation and development.” In Handbook of public economics, 5:51–110. Elsevier.

  • Boix, C. (2003). Democracy and redistribution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonoli, G. (1997). Classifying welfare states: A two-dimension approach. Journal of Social Policy, 26(3), 351–372.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borge, L.-E., & Rattsø, J. (2004). Income distribution and tax structure: Empirical test of the Meltzer–Richard hypothesis. European Economic Review, 48(4), 805–826.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brambor, T. (2016). “Fiscal capacity and the enduring legacy of the first income tax law.” In ECPR joint sessions of workshops 2015.

  • Brewer, J. (1990). The sinews of power: War, money, and the English state, 1688–1783. Harvard University Press.

  • Brülhart, M., & Parchet, R. (2014). Alleged tax competition: The mysterious death of bequest taxes in Switzerland. Journal of Public Economics, 111, 63–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Centeno, M. A. (2003). Blood and debt: War and the nation-state in Latin America. Penn State Press.

  • Charlet, A., & Buydens, S. (2012). The OECD international VAT/GST guidelines: Past and future developments. World Journal of VAT/GST Law, 1(2), 175–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J. A. (1998). Political regimes and the extractive capacity of governments: Taxation in democracies and dictatorships. World Politics, 50(3), 349–376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chile. (1924). “Ley no 4054 sobre Seguros de Enfermedad, Invalidez y Accidentes de Trabajo.”

  • Correlates of War Project. (2017). “State system membership list (V2016).” Folder. 2017. http://correlatesofwar.org. Accessed 15 Dec 2017.

  • Davis, S. L. (1992). IRS historical fact book: A chronology (pp. 1646–1992). Washington, DC: Internal Revenue Service, Department of Treasury.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deloitte. (2017). “Tax guides and country highlights.” 2017. https://dits.deloitte.com/#TaxGuides. Accessed 25 Feb 2018.

  • Dincecco, M., & Katz, G. (2016). State capacity and long-run economic performance. The Economic Journal, 126(590), 189–218.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dincecco, M., & Prado, M. (2012). Warfare, fiscal capacity, and performance. Journal of Economic Growth, 17(3), 171–203.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dincecco, M., Federico, G., & Vindigni, A. (2011). Warfare, taxation, and political change: Evidence from the Italian Risorgimento. The Journal of Economic History, 71(4), 887–914.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Financial Tribune. (2017). “VAT to give way to consumption tax.” Financial Tribune, February 5, 2017.

  • Flora, P. (1983). The growth of mass democracies and welfare states. Campus Verlag.

  • Frankema, E., & van Waijenburg, M. (2014). Metropolitan blueprints of colonial taxation? Lessons from fiscal capacity building in British and French Africa, c. 1880-1940. The Journal of African History, 55(03), 371–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ganghof, S. (2006). The politics of income taxation: A comparative analysis. ECPR Press.

  • Ganghof, S. (2007). The political economy of high income taxation: Capital taxation, path dependence, and political institutions in Denmark. Comparative Political Studies, 40(9), 1059–1084.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gapminder Foundation. 2015. “Gapminder world, gross domestic product per capita by purchasing power parities 2015.” 2015. http://www.temoa.info/node/150/apa. Accessed 24 Sept 2017.

  • Gardner, L. (2012). Taxing colonial Africa: The political economy of British imperialism. Oxford University Press.

  • Gennaioli, N., & Voth, H.-J. (2015). State capacity and military conflict. The Review of Economic Studies, 82(4), 1409–1448.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genovese, F., Scheve, K., and Stasavage, D.. (2016). “Comparative income taxation database.” Stanford.

  • Genschel, P., & Schwarz, P. (2011). Tax competition: A literature review. Socio-Economic Review, 9(2), 339–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genschel, P., & Seelkopf, L. (2016). Did they learn to tax? Taxation trends outside the OECD. Review of International Political Economy, 23(2), 316–344.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genschel, P., Lierse, H., & Seelkopf, L. (2016). Dictators Don’t compete: Autocracy, democracy, and tax competition. Review of International Political Economy, 23(2), 290–315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Genschel, P., & Seelkopf, L. (2019). Codebook - Tax Introduction Dataset Version May 2019. https://www.tid.seelkopf.eu

  • Genser, B., & Reutter, A. (2007). Moving towards dual income taxation in Europe. FinanzArchiv: Public Finance Analysis, 63(3), 436–456.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gouveia, M., & Masia, N. A. (1998). Does the median voter model explain the size of government?: Evidence from the states. Public Choice, 97(1–2), 159–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grafe, R., & Irigoin, M. A. (2006). The Spanish empire and its legacy: Fiscal redistribution and political conflict in colonial and post-colonial Spanish America. Journal of Global History, 1(2), 241–267.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haffert, L., and Mertens, D. (2017). “Between distribution and allocation: Growth models, sectoral coalitions and the politics of taxation revisited.” Harvard CES.

  • Hinrichs, H. H. (1966). A general theory of tax structure change during economic development. Cambridge: Law School of Harvard University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hintze, O. (1906). “Military organization and the Organization of the State.”

  • Hoffman. (1994). “Early modern France, 1450–1700.” In P. T. Hoffman and K. Norberg (ed.) Fiscal crises, liberty, and representative government, 1450–1789. Stanford University Press.

  • ICTD/UNU-WIDER. (2017). “Government revenue dataset.” UNU-WIDER. 2017. https://www.wider.unu.edu/project/government-revenue-dataset.

  • International Tax Dialogue. (2013). Review of International Tax Dialogue, Key Issues and Debates in VAT, SME Taxation and the Tax Treatment of the Financial Sector, by a Carter. International Tax Dialogue.

  • Kato, J. (2003). “Regressive taxation and the welfare state: Path dependence and policy diffusion.” Cambridge Core. September 2003.

  • Keen, M., & Lockwood, B. (2010). The value added tax: Its causes and consequences. Journal of Development Economics, 92(2), 138–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemmerling, A. (2014). How labour ended up taxing itself and why it matters: The long-term evolution of politics in German labour taxation. Journal of European Social Policy, 24(2), 150–163.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenny, L. W., & Winer, S. L. (2006). Tax Systems in the World: An empirical investigation into the importance of tax bases, administration costs, scale and political regime. International Tax and Public Finance, 13(2–3), 181–215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiser, E., & Karceski, S. M. (2017). Political economy of taxation. Annual Review of Political Science, 20(1), 75–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiser, E., & Linton, A. (2001). Determinants of the growth of the state: War and taxation in early modern France and England. Social Forces, 80(2), 411–448.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levi, M. (1989). Of rule and revenue. University of California Press.

  • Lieberman, E. S. (2002). Taxation data as indicators of state-society relations: Possibilities and pitfalls in cross-National Research. Studies in Comparative International Development, 36(4), 89–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lierse, H., & Seelkopf, L. (2014). Tax Introduction Database (TID). Version 13.11.2014

  • Lynch, F. (2013). “The Haig-Shoup Mission to France in the 1920s.” In W. Elliot Brownlee, E. Ide, and Y. Fukagai (ed.) The Political Economy of Transnational Tax Reform: The Shoup Mission to Japan in Historical Context. Cambridge University Press.

  • Mann, M. (1993). The Sources of Social Power: Volume 2, The rise of classes and nation-states, 17601914. Cambridge University Press.

  • Mares, I., & Queralt, D. (2015). The non-democratic origins of income taxation. Comparative Political Studies, 48(14), 1974–2009.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, I. W., Mehrotra, A. K., and Prasad, M. (2009). The new fiscal sociology: Taxation in comparative and historical perspective. Cambridge University Press.

  • McCarty, N., and Pontusson, H. J.. (2011). “The political economy of inequality and redistribution.” In W. Salverda, B. Nolan, and T. M. Smeeding (ed.) The Oxford handbook of economic inequality. Oxford University Press.

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 914–927.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2017). “Revenue statistics - OECD countries.” 2017. https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?DataSetCode=REV. Accessed 3 March 2017.

  • Penndorf, B. (1930). “The relation of taxation to the history of the balance sheet.” Accounting Review, 243–251.

  • Peters, B. G. (1991). The politics of taxation: A comparative perspective. Cambridge: Blackwell Pub.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T., & Saez, E. (2014) “Inequality in the Long Run.” Science 344(6186), 838–843.

  • Plagge, A., Scheve, K., and Stasavage, D. (2010). “Comparative inheritance taxation database.” ISPS data archive. http://isps.yale.edu/research/data/d025.

  • Przeworski, A., and et.al. (2013). “Political institutions and political events (PIPE) data set.” Department of Politics, New York University.

  • PwC. (2017). “World wide tax summaries.” 2017. http://taxsummaries.pwc.com/uk/taxsummaries/wwts.nsf/ID/tax-summaries-home. Accessed 25 Feb 2018.

  • Reid, T. R. (2017). A fine mess: A global quest for a simpler, fairer, and more efficient tax system. Penguin.

  • Rixen, T. (2011). Tax competition and inequality: The case for global tax governance. Global Governance: A Review of Multilateralism and International Organizations, 17(4), 447–467.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sarkees, M. R., & Wayman, F. W. (2010). Resort to war (pp. 1816–2007). Washington, D.C: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, K., & Stasavage, D. (2010). The conscription of wealth: Mass warfare and the demand for progressive taxation. International Organization, 64(04), 529–561.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, K., & Stasavage, D. (2012). Democracy, war, and wealth: Lessons from two centuries of inheritance taxation. American Political Science Review, 106(01), 81–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheve, K., & Stasavage, D. (2016). Taxing the rich: A history of fiscal fairness in the United States and Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1917). The crisis of the tax state. International Economic Papers, 4, 5–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seelkopf, L., Lierse, H., & Schmitt, C. (2016). Trade liberalization and the global expansion of modern taxes. Review of International Political Economy, 23(2), 208–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seligman, E. R. A. (1914). The income tax: A study of the history, theory, and practice of income taxation at home and abroad. The Lawbook Exchange, Ltd.

  • Slemrod, J. (2007). Cheating ourselves: The economics of tax evasion. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(1), 25–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spencer, H. (1898). Principles of sociology, the, Vol. ii. New York: D. Appleton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steinmo, S. (1993). Taxation and democracy: Swedish, British, and American approaches to financing the modern state. Yale University Press.

  • Steinmo, S. (2003). The evolution of policy ideas: Tax policy in the 20th century. The British Journal of Politics and International Relations, 5(2), 206–236.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swank, D. (2006). Tax policy in an era of internationalization: Explaining the spread of neoliberalism. International Organization, 60(4), 847–882.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swank, D., & Steinmo, S. (2002). The new political economy of taxation in advanced capitalist democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 642–655.

  • Tilly, C. (1990). “1990. Coercion, capital, and European states. AD 990.”

  • Titmuss, R. (1958). Essays on the welfare state. London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R., & Weber, W. (1977). Wagner’s law, fiscal institutions, and the growth of government. National Tax Journal, 30(1), 59–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wahl, I., Kastlunger, B., & Kirchler, E. (2010). Trust in Authorities and Power to enforce tax compliance: An empirical analysis of the slippery slope framework. Law and Policy, 32(4), 383–406.

    Google Scholar 

  • Webber, C., & Wildavsky, A. (1986). A history of taxation and expenditure in the Western world (1st ed.). New York: Simon and Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, D. (1996). “Social Security Taxation.” In Tax Law Design and Drafting, edited by Victor Thuronyi. Vol. 1. International Monetary Fund.

  • Yun-Casalilla, B. (2012). Introduction. The rise of fiscal states: A global history, 1500–1914. In B. Yun-Casalilla, P. K. O’Brien, & F. C. Comin (Eds.), The rise of fiscal states: A global history, 1500–1914 (pp. 1–36). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zielinski, R. C. (2016). How states pay for wars. Cornell University Press.

  • Zolt, E. M., & Bird, R. M. (2005). Redistribution via taxation: The limited role of the personal income tax in developing countries. UCLA Law Review, 52(September), 1627–1695.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Guy Whitten, Florian Hollenbach, Christine Lipsmeyer, Didac Queralt, Pablo Beramendi, Melissa Rogers,Carles Boix, José Cheibub, Lucy Martin, Ken Scheve, Hilary Appel, Ewout Frankema, Klaus Schlichte, Suthan Krishnarajan, participants at EPSA 2017/8, ECPR 2018, workshops in Bremen and Vienna, as well as Axel Dreher and three anonymous referees for very helpful comments. The authors gratefully acknowledge funding by the EUI Research Council, 2016–2018, the Robert Schuman Centre for Advanced Studies, and the School of Transnational Governance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Laura Seelkopf.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

ESM 1

(PDF 1.16 mb)

ESM 2

(DO 2 kb)

ESM 3

(CSV 106 kb)

ESM 4

(RDS 78 kb)

ESM 5

(R 59 kb)

ESM 6

(DTA 109 kb)

ESM 7

(DOCX 395 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Seelkopf, L., Bubek, M., Eihmanis, E. et al. The rise of modern taxation: A new comprehensive dataset of tax introductions worldwide. Rev Int Organ 16, 239–263 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-019-09359-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-019-09359-9

Keywords

Navigation