Skip to main content

The Size and Composition of Government Spending in Multi-Party Systems

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Essays on Government Growth

Part of the book series: Studies in Public Choice ((SIPC,volume 40))

Abstract

This paper explores the structure of party competition across democratic nations and its impact on the size and composition of government spending. The analytical framework expands on the norm of universalism, applies it to multi-party legislatures, and develops several propositions. We examine these propositions empirically using panel data for two samples, OECD countries and a large sample of world countries. The findings for both samples indicate that political fragmentation, usually measured by the number of effective political parties, has a positive relationship with the size of the government, and with subsidies and transfers. The findings also indicate that proportional representation (particularly closed lists proportional voting systems) and parliamentary countries favor higher public expenditures.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    McKenzie (2001) presents an up-to-date and complete survey of the recent literature on the relationship between political institutions and fiscal outcomes.

  2. 2.

    Persson and Tabellini (2000, pp. 11–14) present a good overview of the differences between pre-election and post-election models.

  3. 3.

    Systematic data for some of the political variables used in this paper, mainly the absolute and effective number of parties, are not available for a large number of countries and years and had to be gathered from the individual election results. Other papers, like Persson and Tabellini (2001), have already benefited from these data. Recently, efforts that complement the availability of political data have been undertaken by Seddon et al. (2003) and Clarke et al. (2000).

  4. 4.

    Knight (2004) provides evidence contrary to the minimum winning coalition thesis using data for the U.S. Congress. See Matthews (1960), Ferejohn (1974), Fiorina (1974), and Mayhew (1974) for empirical evidence on congressional decision-making and universalistic outcomes. Collie (1988) offers evidence on the evolution of universalism in the U.S. Congress. Cox and Tutt (1984) present evidence on universalism for the Los Angeles County Board of Supervisors.

  5. 5.

    Universalism is informally known as “pork-barrel politics.” Weingast (1979, p. 249) defines universalism as “the tendency to seek unanimous passage of distributive programs through inclusion of a project for all legislators who want one.” See also Niou and Ordeshook (1985) for a formal elaboration of the norm of universalism.

  6. 6.

    Miller and Oppenheimer (1982) present experimental evidence on the prevalence of universalism in committee decision making.

  7. 7.

    Again, because taxes are uniform across the polity, every citizen pays for the cost of every project whether or not he or she benefits from it. Consequently, every legislator has an incentive to include a project in the spending plan that benefits her constituency. The papers by Weingast (1979) and Shepsle and Weingast (1981) offer thorough explanations of the decision problem faced by the legislator and formal proofs of the stability of the equilibrium.

  8. 8.

    Gilligan and Matsusaka (1995, 2001) examine the 1∕n hypothesis empirically using data on American States in the pre-and post-World War II periods. In American State legislatures, where legislators are selected under a plurality rule from (mostly) single-member constituencies, they find a positive and significant correlation between the size of upper legislative chambers and state government expenditures. They also find that the size of state lower chambers has no systematic effect on spending, an interesting result in its own right.

  9. 9.

    According to the data presented in Table 6.1, the median value among regions ranges from three to 9.5 parties. Important for panel data analysis, the number of parties within countries fluctuates over time. The typically large number of parties is not peculiar to the lower houses of parliaments. More than 50% of bicameral countries had at least six parties represented in the upper chamber.

  10. 10.

    These are only a few of the basic differences that have been raised. A large number of books explain the differences among electoral systems in detail. See, for example, Shugart and Taagepera (1989), LeDuc et al. (1996), Katz (1980), Cox (1997), and Lijphart (1999).

  11. 11.

    Lijphart (1999) presents a thorough summary on the determinants of the number of parties. Other relevant studies include Laakso and Taagepera (1979), Shugart and Taagepera (1989), Palfrey (1989), and Lijphart (1990).

  12. 12.

    Duverger’s work was later complemented by Leys’s (1959) thesis that strategic voting occurs not for the two parties that are in the lead locally, but in favor of the two parties that have the largest number of seats in Parliament, regardless of their local strength. Subsequently, Sartori (1968) argued that a plurality rule would have no effect beyond the district until there are parties that have both nationwide organizations and ideological reputations that command a habitual following in the electorate.

  13. 13.

    Most parties in multiple-party systems are highly undemocratic. Choice of candidates unrestricted to all party members is uncommon. The proportion is rarely more than a third of all members and sometimes is as small as 1% of the total number of members of the party. Representatives in the multiple-party system know that there is a big chance that they will not be able to face a next election if they defy the party line. As Gallagher et al. (1992, p. 134) describe, “In Western Europe, self interest requires politicians to put the party first, last, and always. Outside the party there is no salvation, or at least no career path prospect”.

  14. 14.

    For a thorough analysis regarding party discipline and the bargaining among party leaders, see de Dios (1999, p. 150).

  15. 15.

    For example, if there are four parties each with 25% of the seats, ENPP = 4. If one party has 85% of the seats and the other three parties have only 5% each, ENPP is approximately 1.

  16. 16.

    Adopting the ENPP measure is not unique to our work. For example, Lijphart (1994, p. 70) offers the following assessment: “Because the effective number of parties is the purest measure of the number of parties, because it has become the most widely used measure, because the alternative measures are quite similar to it in most respects, and, last but not least, because it is computationally much simpler than the alternatives, it will be my number-of-parties measure in this study.”

  17. 17.

    In order to calculate the number of parties, we aggregated and considered coalitions to be one party if these coalitions announced an agreement before the election and the candidates ran under the name of the common coalition instead of the individual parties.

  18. 18.

    New Zealand moved to a system where half of the seats are awarded by PR and half are chosen by plurality election in single-member districts. Italy shifted to a modified plurality system in which only 25% of the seats were awarded by PR and the rest by voters in single-member districts. For additional details on the institutional change in the 1990s, see Dahl (1996, p. 189).

  19. 19.

    This assumption is only necessary for this simple model but it is not required for the results to be valid.

  20. 20.

    Note that: (b − c) − m(b − c) = (1 − m)(b − c) > 0) for n > 1. A more general proof, where b is not necessarily greater than c, can be found in Niou and Ordeshook (1985). In their set-up, either institutional constraints or repeated games yield the same universalistic outcome.

  21. 21.

    For example, the number of effective parties increases by one as the share of the seats for four parties represented in the legislature changes from (40,39,11,10) to (25,25,25,25). ENPP equals 3 and 4 respectively.

  22. 22.

    Kontopoulos and Perotti (1999) present a similar fiscal commons model to explain the size of the government by focusing on the number of ministers with spending authority.

  23. 23.

    The alternative to PR systems are mixed systems, which elect some legislators from single-member constituencies and some from multi-member constituencies, and plurality or first-pass-the-post systems that elect every legislator from single-member constituencies. This restrictive rule is the closest to the theoretical models of pre-election politics and the most convenient to use in the empirical analysis.

  24. 24.

    Kunicova and Rose-Ackerman (2005) make a similar argument to explain higher corruption in countries with closed list systems versus open list systems. In their model, in closed list proportional systems politicians are first accountable to the party and then to the voters; therefore elections are not as effective as in plurality systems to constrain individuals. Carey and Shugart (1995) show that under closed-lists formulas politicians’ concern about personal reputation and the incentive to cultivate a personal vote are minimal.

  25. 25.

    The size of the legislature has been shown to affect the size of government in a sample for the American States by Gilligan and Matsusaka (1995), US city governments by Baqir (2002), and in a world sample by Bradbury and Crain (2001). However, Pettersson-Lidbom (2012) finds evidence of a negative relationship between the size of the chamber and public expenditures.

  26. 26.

    Other variables we examined but do not report in the text include: land area, population density, urban population, GDP, Gini coefficient, education, bicameralism, ideology of government, governance indicators, and term limits. We also estimated models with the expenditure and openness variables in log form; again, these made no material difference to the results on our variables of interest.

  27. 27.

    Stein et al. (1999) find a similar correlation between the number of effective parties and government expenditure in a sample of Latin American countries. In their model, an additional effective party increases government expenditure as a share of GDP by 2 percentage points. We note that in the Stein et al. (1999) study, the district magnitude (a variable described in the “pre-election politics” models) is not significantly correlated with the size of the government.

  28. 28.

    The average ENPP for proportional representation countries is 3.9 while the average ENPP for the average majoritarian country is 2.4.

  29. 29.

    This result is consistent with the existence of economies of scale in the provision of public goods. In Sect. 6.4, we show that the coefficient for the log of population is negative with respect to public goods and positive with respect to transfers. A higher importance of transfers in the OECD countries explains the change of signs when compared with the world sample.

  30. 30.

    The average ENPP for proportional representation countries is 3.3 while the average ENPP for the average majoritarian country is 2.2.

  31. 31.

    To check the validity of our results, we ran the same specifications using a variable that proxies our political competition variables from Clarke et al. (2000). This variable, government fragmentation (the probability that two random draws will produce legislators from different parties) and the other control variables remained consistent with the results reported in the text.

  32. 32.

    Adams (1996) finds evidence that platforms and policies are more ideologically diverse even in those cases where the number of parties is fixed and cannot accommodate to the proportionality of the electoral system, as is the case with the Illinois General Assembly during the period 1870–1982.

  33. 33.

    See Cox (1990a,b) for a more detailed analysis on multi-candidate spatial competition.

  34. 34.

    As a further distinction, in a two-party system, constituents are able to hold their specific representative accountable. Under government coalitions, lines of responsibility are blurred and each party attempts to blame its partners for failures while taking credit itself for successes. Katz (1980) exposits this distinction.

  35. 35.

    See Tullock (1994, p. 33).

  36. 36.

    This result is also a consequence of a model where legislators have to choose the amount of time, effort, and political capital they invest in producing pork for their district. Bueno de Mesquita (2002) shows that legislators from multi-member districts invest less time and effort in work related to the specific interest of their district constituents than do legislators from single-member districts.

  37. 37.

    Stratmann and Baur (2002) find empirical evidence of different behaviors across legislators for Germany, where half of the parliamentary seats are awarded from single-member constituencies and the other half through proportional voting. The legislators elected from single-member constituencies tend to choose legislative committees that deal with geographically based affairs while the legislators elected by party lists tend to prefer those committees that deal with broad based policies and transfers.

  38. 38.

    For example, 70 legislators from different parties represent the constituents of Provincia de Buenos Aires, Argentina. In this case, the ignorance of voters is very high and the cost for each representative for not serving the constituency very low. On the other side, the cost of not serving the party is very high. Consequently, legislators form demographically based coalitions instead of geographically based.

  39. 39.

    These results are consistent with the literature summarized in Persson and Tabellini (2000). In particular, Alesina and Wacziarg (1998) offer similar evidence on the positive relationship between openness and government transfers.

References

  • Adams GD (1996) Legislative effects of single-member vs. multi-member districts. Am J Polit Sci 40(1):129–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alesina A, Wacziarg R (1998) Openness, country size and government. J Public Econ 69(3):305–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amorim Neto O, Cox GW (1997) Electoral institutions, cleavage structures, and the number of parties. Am J Polit Sci 41(1):149–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks AS, Muller TC, Overstreet PSM William, Smith H (2000) Political Handbook of the World 1999. CQ Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Baqir R (2002) Districting and government overspending. J Polit Econ 110(6):1318–1354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury JC, Crain WM (2001) Legislative organization and government spending: cross-country evidence. J Public Econ 82(3):309–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita E (2002) Less than the sum of its parts: monitoring legislative teamwork in multi-member districts. Harvard University Department of Government, Working Paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron DR (1978) The expansion of the public economy: a comparative analysis. Am Polit Sci Rev 72(4):1243–1261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carey JM, Shugart MS (1995) Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: a rank ordering of electoral formulas. Elect Stud 14(4):417–439

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke G, Beck T, Keefer P, Groff A, Walsh P (2000) New tools and New Tests in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions. World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 2283

    Google Scholar 

  • Collie MP (1988) Universalism and the parties in the US House of Representatives, 1921–1980. Am J Polit Sci 32(4):865–883

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox GW (1990a) Centripetal and centrifugal incentives in electoral systems. Am J Polit Sci 34(4):903–935

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox GW (1990b) Multicandidate spatial competition. In: Enelow J, Hinich M (eds) Advances in the spatial theory of voting. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 179–198

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Cox GW (1997) Making votes count: strategic coordination in the World’s electoral systems. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cox GW, Tutt TN (1984) Universalism and allocative decision making in the Los Angeles County Board of Supervisors. J Polit 46(2):546–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl RA (1996) Thinking about democratic constitutions: Conclusions from democratic experience. Nomos 38(1):175–206

    Google Scholar 

  • de Dios MS (1999) Parliamentary party discipline in spain. In: Bowler S, Farrell D, Katz R (eds) Party discipline in parliamentary governments. Ohio State University Press, Columbus, pp 141–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Deininger K, Squire L (1996) A new data set measuring income inequality. World Bank Econ Rev 10(3):565–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Derbyshire J, Derbyshire I (1996) Political Systems of the World. St Martins Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dollar D, Kraay A (2002) Growth is good for the poor. J Econ Growth 7(3):195–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W (1999) Life during growth. J Econ Growth 4(3):239–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn JA (1974) Pork barrel politics: rivers and harbors legislation, 1947–1968. Stanford University Press, Palo Alto

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina MP (1974) Congress, keystone of the Washington establishment. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Freedom House (Various) Freedom in the World. Freedom House, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher M, Laver M, Mair P (1992) Representative government in Western Europe. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan TW, Matsusaka JG (1995) Deviations from constituent interests: the role of legislative structure and political parties in the states. Econ Inq 33(3):383–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilligan TW, Matsusaka JG (2001) Fiscal policy, legislature size, and political parties: evidence from state and local governments in the first half of the 20th century. Natl Tax J 54(1):57–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney J, Skipton C, Lawson R (2001) Trade openness, income levels, and economic growth, 1980–1998. In: Gwartney J, Lawson R (eds) Economic freedom of the World: 2001 annual report. Fraser Institute, Vancouver, pp 71–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Henisz W (2000) The Political Constraint Index (POLCON) Dataset. University of Pennsylvania, https://mgmt.wharton.upenn.edu/faculty/heniszpolcon/polcondataset/

    Google Scholar 

  • Heston A, Summers R (1995) The Penn World Tables. Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia

    Google Scholar 

  • Inman RP, Fitts MA (1990) Political institutions and fiscal policy: evidence from the US historical record. J Law Econ Organ 6:79–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inter-Parliamentary Union (Various) Chronicle of Parliamentary Elections. International Centre for Parliamentary Documentation, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz RS (1980) A theory of parties and electoral systems. JHU Press, Baltimore, MD

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight B (2004) Bargaining in legislatures: an empirical investigation. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 10530

    Google Scholar 

  • Kontopoulos Y, Perotti R (1999) Government fragmentation and fiscal policy outcomes: evidence from OECD countries. In: Poterba J, von Hagen J (eds) Fiscal institutions and fiscal performance. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 81–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunicova J, Rose-Ackerman S (2005) Electoral rules and constitutional structures as constraints on corruption. Br J Polit Sci 35(4):573–606

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laakso M, Taagepera R (1979) ‘Effective’ number of parties: a measure with application to west Europe. Comp Polit Stud 12(1):3–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LeDuc L, Niemi RG, Norris P (1996) Comparing democracies: elections and voting in global perspective. Sage Publications, Thousand Oaks

    Google Scholar 

  • Leys C (1959) Models, theories, and the theory of political parties. Polit Stud 7(2):127–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart A (1990) The political consequences of political laws. Am Polit Sci Rev 84(2):481–496

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart A (1994) Electoral systems and party systems: a study of twenty-seven democracies, 1945–1990. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart A (1999) Patterns of democracy: government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri A, Persico N (2005) A drawback of electoral competition. J Eur Econ Assoc 3(6):1318–1348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mackie T (1991) The international Almanac of electoral history. Macmillan, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Maddex R (2007) Constitutions of the World. CQ Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Matthews D (1960) US senators and their World. University of North Carolina Press, Chapel Hill

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew DR (1974) Congress: the electoral connection. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie K (2001) A tragedy of the house of commons: political institutions and fiscal policy outcomes from a Canadian perspective. CD Howe Institute, Toronto

    Google Scholar 

  • Milesi-Ferretti GM, Perotti R, Rostagno M (2002) Electoral systems and public spending. Q J Econ 117(2):609–657

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller GJ, Oppenheimer JA (1982) Universalism in experimental committees. Am Polit Sci Rev 76(3):561–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Molinar J (1991) Counting the number of parties: an alternative index. Am Polit Sci Rev 85(4):1383–1391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niou E, Ordeshook P (1985) Universalism in congress. Am J Polit Sci 29(2):246–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook PC, Shvetsova OV (1994) Ethnic heterogeneity, district magnitude, and the number of parties. Am J Polit Sci 38(1):100–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey T (1989) A mathematical proof of Duverger’s Law. In: Ordeshook P (ed) Models of strategic choice in politics. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, pp 69–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G (1999) The size and scope of government: comparative politics with rational politicians. Eur Econ Rev 43(4–6):699–735

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini GE (2000) Political economy: explaining economic policy. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini G (2001) Political institutions and policy outcomes: what are the stylized facts? Centre for Economic Policy Research, Discussion Paper 2872

    Google Scholar 

  • Pettersson-Lidbom P (2012) Does the size of the legislature affect the size of government? Evidence from two natural experiments. J Public Econ 96(3–4):269–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Powell GB (1982) Contemporary democracies: participation, stability, and violence. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rae DW (1967) The political consequences of electoral laws. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker WH (1962) The theory of political coalitions. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (1998) Why do more open economies have bigger governments? J Polit Econ 106(5):997–1032

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogowski R, Kayser MA (2002) Majoritarian electoral systems and consumer power: price-level evidence from the OECD countries. Am J Polit Sci 46(3):526–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sachs J, Wartner A (2010) Trade openness indicators, 1950–1992. Harvard Dataverse. https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/PIZQEZ

  • Sartori G (1968) Political development and political engineering. In: Montgomery J, Hirschman A (eds) Public policy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Seddon J, Gaviria A, Panizza U, Stein E (2003) Political particularism around the world. World Bank Econ Rev 17(1):133–143

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle KA, Weingast BR (1981) Political preferences for the pork barrel: a generalization. Am J Polit Sci 25(1):96–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shugart MS, Taagepera R (1989) Seats and votes. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein E, Talvi E, Grisanti A (1999) Institutional arrangements and fiscal performance: the Latin American experience. In: Poterba J, von Hagen J (eds) Fiscal institutions and Fiscal performance. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 103–133

    Google Scholar 

  • Stratmann T, Baur M (2002) Plurality rule, proportional representation, and the German Bundestag: How incentives to pork-barrel differ across electoral systems. Am J Polit Sci 46(3):506–514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Treisman D (2000) The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. J Public Econ 76(3):399–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock G (1994) Thoughts about representative government. Eur J Polit Econ 10(1):27–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast BR (1979) A rational choice perspective on congressional norms. Am J Polit Sci 23(2):245–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1999) World development indicators. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Gordon Tullock, Richard E. Wagner, Tyler Cowen, Joe Reid, Thomas Stratmann, and participants at the Public Choice Society Meetings in Charleston, SC, and San Antonio, TX, and seminars at George Mason University, Loyola University, and the Inter-American Development Bank for constructive comments in previous drafts of the paper. Remaining errors are our responsibility. The views and interpretations expressed in this paper are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the Inter-American Development Bank, or to any individual acting on its behalf.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to W. Mark Crain .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 6.8, 6.9, and 6.10.

Table 6.8 Summary statistics
Table 6.9 Countries included in the empirical work
Table 6.10 Variables and sources of data

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Scartascini, C.G., Crain, W.M. (2021). The Size and Composition of Government Spending in Multi-Party Systems. In: Hall, J., Khoo, B. (eds) Essays on Government Growth. Studies in Public Choice, vol 40. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-55081-3_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics