Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A Sectoral Approach to the Politics of State Aid in the European Union: an Analysis of the European Automotive Industry

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A growing body of scholarship has been focusing on the determinants of subsidy spending. Yet, this literature has mostly overlooked sectoral approaches to explain variation in aid allocations, which can provide useful insights about state-business relations that macro-analyses cannot. The article explores the political determinants of state aid in a key sector of the European economy, the automotive industry, which represents a crucial test case to analyse the relationship between big firms and the state. The article argues that there are two mechanisms through which governments may choose to allocate aid: achievement of policy goals and electoral competition. The resulting hypotheses are tested on an original dataset of over 120 state aid measures in 16 member states of the European Union (EU) where an automotive industry is present between 1992 and 2011. The results show that aid allocations are seldom found to be determined by a government’s preferences over its policy objectives. Instead, electoral rules such as the cultivation of a personal reputation by distribution of targeted benefits to a constituency may help legislators in their chances of being re-elected. The article concludes with limitations of the present study and suggestions for future research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. One exception is Rickard’s (2018) study on agriculture, fishing and manufacturing in Norway. Here, too, however, the sectors are rather widely defined. Park and Jensen (2007) and Zahariadis (2008) also focus on agricultural subsidies, but these may be ‘special’ cases due to their high level of organisation, homogeneity in interests and other external policies such as the European CAP (Community Agricultural Policy).

  2. See https://www.gazzettaufficiale.it/eli/id/1977/09/07/077U0675/sg.

  3. http://ec.europa.eu/competition/state_aid/register/.

  4. See http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/cases/index/nace_all.html for a full list.

  5. Deal No. 1601416344 in the Zephyr database: see https://zephyr.bvdinfo.com. Daimler divested its Chrysler assets in 2007 for €6.74bn via an institutional buyout: see Deal No. 517310.

  6. Deal No. 1909542683 in the Zephyr database.

  7. Deal No. 69497 in the Zephyr database. Renault increased its ownership of Dacia to 93% in 2001 and attained full ownership by 2004 (see Chari (2015), p. 118).

  8. Deal No. 446877 in the Zephyr database. As of December 2018, Renault has a 100% stake in AvtoVAZ (see Deal No. 1941197083).

  9. OJ C 123 of 18 May 1989.

  10. OJ C 279 of 15 September 1997.

  11. OJ C 368 of 22 December 2001.

  12. OJ C 70 of 19 March 2002.

  13. OJ C 54 of 4 March 2006 and OJ C 209 of 23 July 2013.

  14. OJ C 83 of 7 April 2009.

  15. Common-pool problems increase as the number of policy-makers increases, but diminish when some of these actors are more encompassing, as they can better internalise the costs (Bawn and Rosenbluth 2006). Common pools are less problematic in a situation where three policy-makers represent 49%, 49% and 2% of the total, than in one in which each is 33%. In the first case, the third actor is less problematic because she will get less credit (blame), so the effective number of actors is two.

  16. http://ec.europa.eu/competition/publications/annual_report/. Crisis aid, such as that given under the Temporary Framework, is excluded from the analysis.

  17. In the latter case, the Commission registers Volkswagen as the beneficiary.

  18. https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/IP_00_161.

  19. ‘Need for wage and tax policies to induce enterprise; encouragement to start enterprises; need for financial and other incentives such as subsidies.’

  20. Independents were scored 0. This also reflects the idea exposed by Franzese (2010, pp. 350-352) that the resulting policy from a set of policy-makers with different preferences will be a convex combination, or weighted average, thereof. Some may argue that portfolio allocation in coalition governments may be important in this respect. Common sense suggests that the preferences of the Minister of Industry in matters of state aid must weigh more than those of the Minister of Education, if the two belong to different parties. However, I do not differentiate portfolio allocations for two reasons. First is analytical simplicity. In many cases, subsidies reflect the overall government strategy rather than the individual ministries’, and distinguishing portfolio allocations would needlessly complicate the model. Secondly, empirical evidence found that correlation between portfolio preferences and cabinet posts is rather weak and that the theoretical assumptions about the importance of portfolio allocation on policy output are not convincing (for a review, see Hartmann 2014, pp. 94-99).

  21. 0 is for caretaker governments (e.g. Czechia under Jan Fischer). The formula for effective number of parties (ENP) in government is calculated following Laakso and Taagepera (1979): \(\text {ENP} = \frac {1}{{\sum }_{i=1}^{n} {p}_{i}^{2}}\) where n is the number of parties with at least one seat and \({p}_{i}^{2}\) is the square of each party’s proportion of all seats. Thus, if there are three parties with 50%, 40% and 10% of the seats in the cabinet, the resulting ENP is \(\frac {1}{0.5^{2}+0.4^{2}+0.1^{2}} = 2.38\), which is then approximated to 2.

  22. The Left-Right index is explained in Jahn (2011a).

  23. Portugal, a semi-Presidential unicameral system, presents a more complicated example. In 2002, in Portugal, there was also a coalition government. Thus, there are two relevant actors: the President and the coalition partner. However, since the absorption rule states that any veto player situated within the unanimity core of any set of veto players has no effect on policy stability (Tsebelis 2002), then the range must be calculated by measuring the most extreme positions of two of the three actors (the President and the two most extreme coalition partners) on the Left-Right spectrum. The ideological position of one of the coalition partners (2.53) falls between the most extreme values given by the President (1.73) and the other extreme coalition partner (3.38). Hence, the ideological range is calculated by subtracting the position of the President from that of the more extreme coalition partners.

  24. Additional regression analyses that condition District Magnitude on each individual indicator are in line with the theory.

  25. Franchino and Mainenti (2013) find evidence that when the three of them are low, governments have fewer incentives to engage in particularistic spending, but not the contrary.

  26. \(\text {Timing } = \frac {M + (D/30)}{12}\), where M = pre-election months and D = pre-election days.

  27. EUKLEMS, which provides data for this variable, only records data from 1995 for many member states. This is due to the different classification codes that national account statistics used before then, creating a methodological break. However, EUKLEMS also provides back-cast estimates of ISIC Rev. 4 industries, based on growth rates of ISIC Rev. 3 industries, which allow for a 1:1 comparability with NACE Rev. 2. I would like to thank Monika Schwarzhappel for raising this issue.

  28. I follow Nicolini et al. (2017) in their definition of a national champion as a historical brand (e.g. also Opel in Germany). Additional analyses only including Volksvagen, PSA/Renault and Fiat as national champions do not change the results.

  29. For a more comprehensive understanding of the ZINB estimation, see Garay et al. (2011). See also Hilbe (2011) and Hilbe (2014) and Hardin and Hilbe (2018).

  30. Country and year dummy variables cannot be included in both parts of the equation, since this will prevent model convergence.

  31. It should be noted that by ‘legislators’ I mean parliamentarians sitting either in the lower or upper house.

  32. The Netherlands is excluded for graphical reasons (District Magnitude = 150).

  33. The number of observations in the PPML models is lower because the estimator automatically deletes problematic observations that prevent convergence. See Correia et al. (2020).

  34. By ‘political constituency’ I mean the grouping of voters that belong to or voted for a particular party. This is different from the typical understanding of constituency, which is a geographic electoral reality, as it is used elsewhere in the article.

  35. However, one should also be wary of direct state aid comparisons before and after 2012, as the SAM changed some of the guidelines regarding categorisation of aid.

  36. https://www.ft.com/content/92ff16ec-2162-11ea-92da-f0c92e957a96.

References

  • ACEA (2019a) ACEA Pocket guide 2018-2019

  • ACEA (2019b) Consolidated registration figures

  • Armingeon K, Isler C, Knöpfel L, Weisstanner D, Engler S (2016) Comparative political data set 1960-2014

  • Atkinson MM, Coleman WD (1989) Strong states and weak states: sectoral policy networks in advanced capitalist economies. Br J Polit Sci 19(1):47–67

    Google Scholar 

  • Aydin U (2006) Politics of state aid in the European Union: subsidies as distributive politics. In: Fifteenth international conference of the council for European studies, Chicago, IL, 29 March-1 April, 2006

  • Aydin U (2007) Promoting industries in the global economy: subsidies in OECD countries, 1989 to 1995. J Eur Public Policy 14(1):115–131

    Google Scholar 

  • Bawn K, Rosenbluth F (2006) Short versus long coalitions: electoral accountability and the size of the public sector. Am J Political Sci 50(2):251–265

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry WD, Golder M, Milton D (2012) Improving tests of theories positing interaction. J Polit 74(3):653–671

    Google Scholar 

  • Blais A (1986) The political economy of public subsidies. Comp Polit Stud 19(2):201–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Brambor T, Clark WR, Golder M (2006) Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Polit Anal 14(1):63–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Break GF (1972) Subsidies as an instrument for achieving public economy goals. In: US Congress, Joint Economic Committee, The Economics of Federal Subsidy programs–A Compendium of Papers, 92nd Congress, 2nd Session, Government Printing Office, pp 1–6

  • Cao X, Prakash A, Ward MD (2007) Protecting jobs in the age of globalization: Examining the relative salience of social welfare and industrial subsidies in OECD countries. Int Stud Q 51(2):301–327

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey J, Hix S (2013) Between science and engineering: Reflections on the APSA presidential task force on political science, electoral rules, and democratic governance: Consequences of electoral rules for patterns of redistribution and regulation. Perspect Polit 11(3):820–824

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey J, Shugart MS (1995) Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: a rank ordering of electoral formulas. Elect Stud 14(4):417–439

    Google Scholar 

  • CCFA (2017) L’industrie autmobile Francaisȩ. Analyse et statistiques

  • Chari R (2004) State aids in the Airline Sector: a comparative analysis of Iberia and Aer Lingus studies in public policy. Trinity College Policy Institute, Dublin

  • Chari R (2015) Life after privatization. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Cini M (2001) The soft law approach: Commission rule-making in the EU’s state aid regime. J Eur Public Policy 8(2):192–207

    Google Scholar 

  • Correia S, Guimarães P., Zylkin T (2020) Fast Poisson estimation with high-dimensional fixed effects. Stata J 20(1):95–115

    Google Scholar 

  • Crisp BF, Jensen N, Rosas G, Zeitzoff T (2010) Vote-seeking incentives and investment environments: The need for credit claiming and the provision of protectionism. Elect Stud 29(2):221–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Dancet G, Rosenstock M (1995) State aid control by the European Commission. The case of the automobile sector

  • Dewatripont M, Seabright P (2006) “Wasteful” public spending and State aid control. J Eur Econ Assoc 4(2-3):513–522

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs A (1957) An economic theory of democracy. Harper and Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunnett P (1980) The decline of the British motor industry: The effects of government policy, 1945-79. Routledge, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards MS, Thames FC (2007) District magnitude, personal votes, and government expenditures. Electoral Studies 26(2):338–345

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich SD (2007) Access to protection: Domestic institutions and trade policy in democracies. Int Org 61(3):571–605

    Google Scholar 

  • Elwert F, Winship C (2014) Endogenous selection bias: The problem of conditioning on a collider variable. Ann Rev Soc 40:31–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Engler F, Zohlnhöfer R. (2019) Left parties, voter preferences, and economic policy-making in Europe. J Eur Public Policy 26(11):1620–1638

    Google Scholar 

  • EU KLEMS (2019) EU KLEMS Growth and Productivity Accounts: Statistical Module, ESA 2010 and ISIC Rev. 4 industry classification

  • European Commission (1983) XIII report on competition policy

  • European Commission (1984) XIV report on competition policy

  • European Commission (1990) The effect of different State aid measures on intra-Community competition. EU Publications, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (1997) Information from the Commission - Community Framework For State aid to the motor vehicle industry

  • European Commission (2014) State aid in the automotive sector: an overview Competition policy brief 12. DG Competition, Brussels

  • Featherstone K, Papadimitriou D (2007) Manipulating rules, contesting solutions: Europeanization and the politics of restructuring olympic airways. Gov Oppos 42(1):46–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Franchino F, Mainenti M (2013) Electoral institutions and distributive policies in parliamentary systems: an application to state aid measures in EU countries. West Eur Polit 36(3):498–520

    Google Scholar 

  • Franchino F, Mainenti M (2016) The electoral foundations to noncompliance: addressing the puzzle of unlawful state aid in the European Union. J Public Policy 36(3):407–436

    Google Scholar 

  • Franzese RJ (2002) Macroeconomic policies of developed democracies. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Franzese RJ (2010) The multiple effects of multiple policymakers: Veto actors bargaining in common pools. Rivista italiana di scienza politica 40 (3):341–370

    Google Scholar 

  • Garay AM, Hashimoto EM, Ortega EM, Lachos VH (2011) On estimation and influence diagnostics for zero-inflated negative binomial regression models. Comput Stat Data Anal 55(3):1304–1318

    Google Scholar 

  • Garrett G (1998) Partisan politics in the Global Economy. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Germano L (2009) Governo e grandi imprese: la Fiat da azienda protetta a global player. Il Mulino, Bologna

  • Germano L (2012) FIAT goes it alone: the italian car industry, the government and the crisis of the 2000s. South Eur Soc Politics 17(1):65–86

    Google Scholar 

  • Golden M, Picci L (2008) Pork-barrel politics in postwar Italy, 1953–94. Am J Political Sci 52(2):268–289

    Google Scholar 

  • Golder M (2018) Democratic electoral systems, 1946-2016 dataset (Version 3.0)

  • Gourieroux C, Monfort A, Trognon A (1984) Pseudo maximum likelihood methods: applications to Poisson models. Econometrica 52:701–720

    Google Scholar 

  • Grigolon L, Leheyda N, Verboven F (2016) Scrapping subsidies during the financial crisis—Evidence from Europe. Int J Ind Org 44:41–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (1994) Protection for sale. Am Econ Rev 84(4):833–850

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman GM, Helpman E (2005) A protectionist bias in majoritarian politics. Q J Econ 120(4):1239–1282

    Google Scholar 

  • Gygli S, Haelg F, Sturm J.-E. (2018) The KOF Globalisation Index – Revisited. KOF Working Paper 439, ETH Zurich

  • Hardin JW, Hilbe JM (2018) Generalized linear models and extensions, 3rd edn. Stata Press, Lakeway Drive

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart DM (2004) “Business” Is not an interest group: on the study of companies in american national politics. Annu Rev Polit Sci 7:47–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartmann S (2014) Partisan policy-making in western europe: How ideology influences the content of government policies. Springer, Mannheim

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayward J (1995) Industrial enterprise and European integration: From national to international champions in Western Europe. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilbe JM (2011) Negative binomial regression, 2nd edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilbe JM (2014) Modeling count data. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofmann H (2016) State aid review in a multi-level system: motivations for aid, why control it, and the evolution of state aid law in the EU. In: Hofmann H, Micheau C (eds) State aid law of the European union. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 3–11

  • Hwang W, Lee H (2014) Globalization, factor mobility, partisanship, and compensation policies. Int Stud Q 58(1):92–105

    Google Scholar 

  • Jahn D (2011a) Conceptualizing left and right in comparative politics: towards a deductive approach. Party Polit 17(6):745–765

    Google Scholar 

  • Jahn D (2011b) The veto player approach in macro-comparative politics: concepts and measurement. In: König T, Tsebelis G, Debus M (eds) Reform processes and policy change: veto players and decision-making in modern democracies. Springer, New York, pp 43–68

  • Jahn D, Behm T, Düpont N., Oberst C, Rachuj M (2017) PIP – Parties, Institutions and Preferences: ASPM Replication [Version 2017-02]

  • Johnson JW, Wallack JS (2012) Electoral systems and the personal vote database.

  • Keele L, Stevenson RT, Elwert F (2020) The causal interpretation of estimated associations in regression models. Polit Sci Res Methods 8(1):1–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Laakso M, Taagepera R (1979) “Effective” number of parties: a measure with application to West Europe. Comp Polit Stud 12(1):3–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster TD (1986) Electoral structures and pork barrel politics. Int Political Sci Rev 7(1):67–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindblom CE (1977) Politics and markets: the world’s political-Economics systems basic books, New York, NY

  • Maloney WA, McLaughlin A (1999) The european automobile industry: Multi level governance policy and politics. Routledge, London and New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin LW, Vanberg G (2011) Parliaments and coalitions: The role of legislative institutions in multiparty governance. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin LW, Vanberg G (2013) Multiparty government, fiscal institutions, and public spending. J Polit 75(4):953–967

    Google Scholar 

  • Micheau C (2016) Evolution of state aid rules: conceptions, challenges, and outcomes. In: Hofmann H, Micheau C (eds) State aid law of the European union. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 18–35

  • Neven DJ (1994) The political economy of state aids in the european community: Some econometric evidence. CEPR Discussion Paper, pp 945

  • Nicolini M, Scarpa C, Valbonesi P (2013) Aiding car producers in the EU: money in search of a strategy. J Ind Competition Trade 13(1):67–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicolini M, Scarpa C, Valbonesi P (2017) Determinants of state aid to firms: the case of the European automotive industry. Ind Corp Change 26 (3):399–420

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus WD (1975) The political business cycle. Rev Econ Stud 42(2):169–190

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2001) Competition policy in subsidies and state aid DAFFE/CLP(2001)24. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Pardi T (2017) Industrial policy and the British automotive industry under Margaret Thatcher. Bus Hist 59(1):75–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Park JH, Jensen N (2007) Electoral competition and agricultural support in OECD countries. Am J Political Sci 51(2):314–329

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T (2002) Do political institutions shape economic policy? Econometrica 70(3):883–905

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini GE (2000) Political economics: explaining economic policy. MIT Press, Cambridge and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson T, Tabellini GE (2003) The economic effects of constitutions. MIT Press, Cambridge and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Perumean-Chaney SE, Morgan C, McDowall D, Aban I (2013) Zero-inflated and overdispersed: what’s one to do? J Stat Comput Simul 83(9):1671–1683

    Google Scholar 

  • Rickard SJ (2012a) A non-Tariff protectionist bias in majoritarian politics: Government subsidies and electoral institutions. Int Stud Q 56(4):777–785

    Google Scholar 

  • Rickard SJ (2012b) Welfare versus subsidies: governmental spending decisions in an era of globalization. J Polit 74(4):1171–1183

    Google Scholar 

  • Rickard SJ (2018) Spending to win: political institutions, economic geography and government subsidies. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rogowski R, Kayser MA (2002) Majoritarian electoral systems and consumer power: price-level evidence from the OECD countries. Am J Political Sci 526–539

  • Russo F (2011) The constituency as a focus of representation: Studying the Italian case through the analysis of parliamentary questions. J Legis Stud 17 (3):290–301

    Google Scholar 

  • Schito M (2020) The politics of State aid in the European Union: explaining variation in aid allocation among Member States. J Public Policy. Forthcoming

  • Schmitt C (2016) Panel data analysis and partisan variables: how periodization does influence partisan effects. J Eur Public Policy 23(10):1442–1459

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva JMCS, Tenreyro S (2006) The log of gravity. Rev Econ Stat 88(4):641–658

    Google Scholar 

  • Stephen R (2000) Vehicle of influence: building a European car market. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Thatcher M (2014) European Commission merger control: Combining competition and the creation of larger European firms. Eur J Polit Res 53(3):443–464

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomson R, Royed T, Naurin E, Artés J., Costello R, Ennser-Jedenastik L, Ferguson M, Kostadinova P, Moury C, Pétry F. (2017) The fulfillment of parties’ election pledges: a comparative study on the impact of power sharing. Am J Political Sci 61(3):527–542

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis G (2002) Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Verdier D (1995) The politics of public aid to private industry the role of policy networks. Comp Polit Stud 28(1):3–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Volkens A, Lehman P, Matthieß T, Merz N, Regel S, Weßels B (2017) The Manifesto Data Collection. Manifesto Project (MRG/CMP/MARPOR). Version 2017a

  • Weingast BR, Shepsle KA, Johnsen C (1981) The political economy of benefits and costs: a neoclassical approach to distributive politics. J Polit Econ 89 (4):642–664

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilks S (1988) Industrial policy and the motor industry. Manchester University Press, Manchester

    Google Scholar 

  • Woll C (2019) Corporate power beyond lobbying

  • Wren C (1996) Industrial subsidies: the UK experience. Springer, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu T (2018) The curse of bigness: antitrust in the new gilded age. Columbia Global Reports, New York, NY

  • Yang S, Harlow LL, Puggioni G, Redding CA (2017) A comparison of different methods of zero-inflated data analysis and an application in health surveys. J Mod Appl Stat Methods 16(1):518–543

    Google Scholar 

  • Zahariadis N (1997) Why state subsidies? evidence from European community countries, 1981–1986. Int Stud Q 41(2):341–354

    Google Scholar 

  • Zahariadis N (2005) Policy networks, elections, and state subsidies. Rev Policy Res 22(2):115–131

    Google Scholar 

  • Zahariadis N (2008) State subsidies in the global economy. Palgrave Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Zahariadis N (2010) State aid and partisan government in the european union. Soc Sci Q 91(2):436–454

    Google Scholar 

  • Zahariadis N (2013) Winners and losers in EU state aid policy. J Ind Competition Trade 13(1):143–158

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Luca Bellodi, Raj Chari, Michele Crepaz, Mattia Guidi, Eleonora La Spada and Giulia Saydon, as well as two anonymous reviewers and the editors of the journal for invaluable comments and suggestions. A previous version of the article was presented to the 2019 SISP Conference in Lecce, Italy. I also acknowledge the support of the Irish Research Council, which funded this project.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marco Schito.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interests

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 279 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Schito, M. A Sectoral Approach to the Politics of State Aid in the European Union: an Analysis of the European Automotive Industry. J Ind Compet Trade 21, 1–31 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-020-00348-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-020-00348-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation