Skip to main content
Intended for healthcare professionals
Free access
Research article
First published online January 9, 2020

Revisionist Conflict and State Repression

Abstract

What kinds of international conflicts make states more likely to increase repression? I argue that the issues at stake in conflict may have different levels of domestic salience and may alter the domestic political status quo, thus increasing or decreasing a state’s or regime’s propensity to repress. I argue and find that democracies are most likely to increase repression when they are territorial revisionists, specifically increasing the use of imprisonment and torture. Autocratic states are more likely to increase repression during foreign policy-oriented disputes, as opposed to those fought over territory, which are less likely to escalate to full-scale war, and more likely to be domestically motivated. This project thus opens up the black box of international conflict to better understand how the reasons states fight abroad affects decisions to repress at home.

Introduction

How does involvement in an international conflict affect domestic repression? Prior research has typically shown there to be some relationship between involvement in conflict abroad and repression at home (see for example Davenport (2007b)). Previous work from war-making and state building literature has also emphasized that threats from abroad can help solidify executive authority domestically, which can lead to increasingly repressive and authoritarian states (Gibler, 2010; 2012). I argue that how the conflict affects repression domestically is a function of the issue of the conflict itself and domestic institutions. Not all states’ conflict behavior is the same, and because democratic and autocratic governments differ in fundamental ways with what they have achieved domestically to stay in office, their domestic repressive responses to international conflict will also be different.
International conflict has long been associated with increases in state repression. Well-known studies ranging from Poe and Tate (1994) to Davenport (2007b) find a statistically significant effect of international war involvement and increases in repression. Although prior studies certainly have not ignored international conflict as a factor in repression, I believe international conflict and how it affects domestic politics has been theoretically underspecified. A large amount of research on international conflict, ranging from the democratic peace research program (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003), to more recent work focused on leaders (Chiozza and Goemans, 2011), as well as work on how civil and international conflict are connected (Gleditsch et al., 2008; Salehyan, 2009), has identified a large amount of variance for the domestic motivations of international conflict participation. Because of such variance, it is unreasonable to think that international conflict affects domestic repression in a uniform way. Furthermore, recent research has investigated how autocrats specifically behave in international conflicts (Weeks, 2014), but we know little about how the issues contested in particular conflicts may affect the domestic politics of states.
In this project, I contend that repression occurs during international conflict as a way to boost a regime’s political strength while engaging in a salient conflict abroad. Which conflicts affect domestic repression will differ according to the issue, role, and regime type of involved states. Whereas much of the prior work on international conflict and repression has focused on full-scale international war over any issue (Davenport, 2007b), or focuses specifically on territorial conflict (Gibler, 2012; Wright, 2014), I expand the issue set to include conflicts fought over policy or when regimes are at stake. By role, I mean whether a state is a revisionist state in the conflict. The issue of the conflict is key because conflicts’ salience varies with a regime’s key audiences according to the nature of what is at stake. Specifically, I contend that democracies will be most likely to increase repression when they are contesting territory in conflict, because territory can appeal to the very public sense of identity and nationalism. In turn, this could place public pressure on states to increase domestic security. Therefore, democratic states will be more likely to increase repression, with public support, against groups seen as hindering the territorial effort, such as potential fifth columns. Autocratic states, if they are engaging in international conflict and repression as a means of boosting strength (Chiozza and Goemans, 2011), will seek issue conflicts that are less dangerous (non-territorial) and may tie the most into domestic politics. Policy disputes, which among other causes may involve the pursuit of transnational rebellion, are a likely issue conflict in which autocracies will increase repression.
I find that democracies are most likely to increase repression when they are territorial revisionists, specifically increasing the use of imprisonment and torture, whereas autocratic states are most likely to increase repression when they are revisionists in policy conflicts, increasing the uses of torture, killings, and disappearances. Furthermore, this article also examines how interstate conflict roles and issues affect decisions to repress in specific ways, examining overall repression as well as levels of imprisonment, torture, killings, and disappearances. The findings suggest that exploring the variety of ways in which different kinds of international conflict affects domestic politics has implications for both studies of repression as well as research on interstate conflict.

Structures, shocks, and repression

Foundational work on repression (Poe and Tate, 1994; Davenport, 1995) generated predictions and the bases of explanation that have held up quite well over time. Poe and Tate (1994) build their arguments and expectations on the concept of the “strength/threat” ratio. Explicated in greater detail by Poe (2004), the strength/threat ratio explains repressive output as a calculation a state leader (or government as a whole) makes about its perceived domestic strength relative to the level of threat it experiences or perceives. Whenever a government feels its threat level becomes uncomfortable relative to its level of political strength, repression becomes more likely. From this conceptual base, prior research has identified a few key factors for understanding repression: democracy and economic development that lower repression, and large populations and conflict involvement that increase repression (Poe and Tate, 1994; Davenport, 1995; Davenport, 2007a).
This prior research has essentially identified structural factors and shock factors to explain repression dynamics.1 Understanding the difference of how these structural and shock variables affect repression gives us more explanatory power for understanding repression as a phenomenon. Structural variables, which are political institutions, economic development, and population, do not change much over time. If factors such as economic development, population, and regime type remain relatively stable, we can expect fairly consistent levels of repression year in and year out for such countries.2 Thus, structural factors lead to a set of baseline expectations for a country’s repressiveness. Given the wealth of arguments and findings surrounding democracies, we can expect their baseline levels of repression to be fairly low, and that of autocratic states to be higher. Given this, expectations for how shock variables affect repression should take into account these baseline levels of repression.
Shock factors can lead to rapid changes in repression over short periods of time, particularly those that present direct challenges to the state. Davenport (2007a) and Hafner-Burton (2014), in reviewing the social science literature on repression, both note that research has identified a strong relationship between the presence of domestic political threat and increases in state repression. Specifically if dissent is directed at, and violent against, the state, the state responds by increasing repression, what Davenport (2007a, 7) and others have dubbed the “law of coercive responsiveness.” Civil conflict, more than other factors, involves direct confrontation between opposition forces and the forces of the state, and essentially demands coercive action. When a state experiences a civil conflict, for instance, its regime is being directly threatened by a rebel organization, and thus we would expect states to increase repression relative to where they were before. Assuming the civil war ends with a return to the political status quo, we might also expect repression levels to return to about where they were before the civil war. Other factors that can serve as exogenous or endogenous shocks to the repressive status quo are interstate conflict or some form of external threat (Gibler, 2012; Wright, 2014), economic sanctions (Wood, 2008), natural disasters (Wood and Wright, 2016), or hosting of large numbers of refugees (Wright and Moorthy, 2018).
Although international conflict is also one of these shock factors that affects how repressive a state is, there is no reason to think it does so in a uniform fashion. Davenport (2004, 549–550) notes that interstate war involvement could lead to two opposing processes occurring that affect repression: restricting the capacity of states’ focus on domestic issues, leading to less repression or less deadly forms of repression, or compelling states to increase repression because they seek even more control domestically to pursue conflict abroad. Empirically, results on international conflict involvement and repression have been mixed. Davenport (2007b) finds a positive and significant relationship between interstate war participation and repression, but it is a much weaker relationship than for civil wars. The most comprehensive recent research on the systematic predictors of state repression (Hill and Jones, 2014) find a weak link at best between international war involvement and increases in state repression. Interstate war is a very rare phenomenon and has a high threshold of violence, typically 1000 battle-deaths, for a conflict to be included as a war (Sarkees and Wayman, 2010). Research that employs international war as a control variable may not be accounting for variations in repression that occur from lower intensity interstate conflict or variations in repression that occur across conflicts fought for different reasons.
Whether a state is pulled away from focusing on domestic politics, and thus decreasing repression, or employing international conflict as an opportunity to increase repression may be a function of why the state is fighting and the characteristics of the state itself. We know from prior research that certain kinds of international conflict may be more domestically related than others. Aside from the democratic peace findings that indicate democratic and autocratic states may have fundamentally different calculations and political concerns when deciding to enter conflict (Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003)), recent work by Chiozza and Goemans (2011) and by Salehyan (2009) theoretically explore other domestic purposes for being involved in international conflict, from “gambling” to stay in office to pursuing rebels across a border.
Chiozza and Goemans (2011) develop a domestic-politics driven theory of international conflict. They explain that when leaders experience a temporary shock to their level of domestic support, commitment problems can emerge between the leader and relevant opposition, which can provide an opportunity for challenges to the leadership. Conceptually, this is similar to a shock in the “strength/threat” ratio (Poe, 2004) described above, which provides the window of opportunity for repression. International conflict can resolve the commitment problem in one of two ways, either the successful pursuit of conflict can boost domestic support, or it can nullify opposition to the leadership, either via putting opposing generals in the battlefield or taking away an issue over which they can compete for support. Domestic repression during involvement in an international conflict is a tool that can aid the regime in consolidating support domestically, either by repressing potential fifth columns that are seen as tied to the enemy in an international conflict, or by repressing other domestic opposition because it is opportune. That said, not all international conflicts are alike, and some are more likely to provide the opportunities for repression more than others. I contend this will occur as a function of both the issues at stake in the conflict, as well as the regime type of the state, which conditions the types of domestic political pressures leaders face.
The salience of international conflicts can vary greatly. Although civil conflicts may typically be salient to the central state as either a threat to the territorial integrity of state during secessionist conflicts or direct threat to the state’s ability to control national institutions, international conflicts are often lower intensity or fought over issues that may not resonate domestically. The vast majority of militarized disputes, for instance, never escalate to full-scale war. Thus it may be unreasonable to think that domestic audiences would feel sufficiently mobilized or insecure by all international conflicts. Furthermore, whether an international conflict is domestically salient is a function of domestic political dynamics. Thus, whether interstate conflict involvement will lead to increased repression is a function of whether it resonates with a leader’s key support coalition. We can expect, based on the above discussion, the conflict issues that are more resonant with the general public will be more likely to lead to repression in large coalition states, whereas conflict issues more relevant to the elite will be more likely to spur repression in small coalition systems. Thus, the key things that any model of how state repression is affected by international conflict needs to break down are: a) the issues at stake in the conflict and b) how they relate to the characteristics and preferences of support coalitions.

Issues at stake in international conflict

International conflict can be fought over a variety of issues. Despite major progress in recent decades, political science’s understanding of the way that issues influence the onset and escalation of international conflict remains limited (Diehl, 2013). For decades, issues were considered a secondary cause for international conflict compared to attributes of the states fighting, such as military capability (Diehl, 1992). The foundational literature in the issue approach to understanding conflict (Mansbach and Vasquez, 1981; Vasquez, 1983; Vasquez and Mansbach, 1984) focuses on the tangibility or intangibility of issues and argues the less tangible issues between disputing states are, the more likely conflict is to arise between them. International conflict researchers have typically employed three different issue dimensions: territory, policy, and regime. Territorial conflicts are ones in which a revisionist state seeks to take (or take back) some piece of land. Policy conflicts are ones in which one state attempts to alter the foreign policy practices of another states, whereas regime conflicts are those in which a state’s ruling regime is being targeted by another state for removal from power. Revisionist states are those that seek some change in the issue area over the course of the conflict, as thus any or all states involved may be revisionists (Jones et al., 1996).
Since the early work exploring the role of territorial conflict on the escalation to war (Vasquez, 1993), we know that territorial disputes are the most likely issue over which states escalate militarized disputes to war (Senese and Vasquez, 2008). Territory as an issue links to basic economic, psychological, and identity ties, and is an issue over which hardliners may be able to bid for domestic political gain, making hawkish foreign policy more likely (Vasquez, 1993; Goddard, 2006; Gibler, 2012).3 Research has also consistently shown that territory has dramatic domestic political consequences. Gibler (2012) explains that territorial threat can lead to the centralization of domestic political power in executives, thus promoting autocratic regimes, whereas the lack of territorial competition may allow for more open political systems to emerge. Owsiak (2012; 2013) also shows that having stable or settled borders not only promotes long-term peace but also democratization.4
Although there is a wealth of literature exploring interstate conflict over territory, or the role of borders and land in international conflict, there is much less that examines the specific characteristics of the policy and regime conflicts. Diehl (2013) is critical of the lack of development in research that theoretically and empirically explores these issues. Given the overwhelming importance that regime type plays in conflict processes, conflicts where a state’s regime is the primary focus should certainly receive more attention. Regarding policy conflicts and their categorization in data and (lack of) theoretical attention, he notes that policy conflicts are “a polyglot of cases that no one, to this writer’s knowledge, has sought to unpack” (Diehl, 2013, 269). That said, although the central focus of the work on the linkages between civil and international conflict is focused more on the movement of rebel groups across borders or how civil wars can lead to interstate disputes (Trumbore, 2003; Salehyan, 2009), these disputes would often be considered either focusing on policy or regime. Such disputes would clearly have domestic political importance. Being the targets of regime conflicts in particular may present an existential threat for governments and regimes and thus be of primary importance domestically. That said, of the issues in interstate conflict, regime disputes are the rarest, whereas policy disputes are far more common.5
Given the divergent goals that interstate conflicts have for revisionist states, it is unreasonable to think these conflicts affect domestic politics, specifically repression, in a uniform way. I contend, like other work (Davenport, 2007b; Gibler, 2012), that the best way to understand how conflict will affect repressiveness is to explore international conflict through the lens of domestic political institutions. We know from work that explores the democratic peace phenomenon (Huth and Allee, 2002; Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003; Chiozza and Goemans, 2011), democracies and autocracies have different priorities and goals for interstate conflict involvement, with democracies being more careful in selecting conflicts abroad in which they can ensure victory (a public good), whereas autocratic states might be more willing to gamble about victory when pursuing interstate conflicts (Huth and Allee, 2002; Chiozza and Goemans, 2011).
Below I lay out my general expectations for democratic and autocratic states. Given that democracies and autocracies approach conflict and repression differently, it seems reasonable to tell two theoretical stories. Below I make an argument that among the different types of international conflict issues, territorial ones are the most likely to lead to increases in repression by democratic states, whereas interstate disputes fought over policy disagreements are most likely to lead to increased by repression.

Conflict issues and domestic support coalitions: Expectations for democratic states

Democratic and autocratic states have fundamentally different approaches when it comes to repression. Ideally and conceptually, we imagine democracies to be systems in which leaders are kept in check through regular elections and must provide the public with generally accessible services and security (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003). We know from prior work that democracies are also likely to be much less repressive, on the whole, than autocratic states (Davenport and Armstrong, 2004; Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2005; Davenport, 2007b). Davenport (2007b) provides the most comprehensive investigation of how democracy and conflict interact and affect repression. He argues there are two major forces working to keep repression in democracies low. One is voice, which is the public choice mechanisms of elections, and the other is veto, which is the ability of political institutions to check the executive. Democracies typically maintain lower repression because they not only have to rely on public support to stay in office (voice) and repressing elements of the public may hurt their chances electorally, but also because of institutional checks at the elite level (veto). Davenport (2007b) finds that conflict can weaken both of these mechanisms’ ability to check against increases in state repression. A major domestic factor motivating democratic policy making is the need to deliver public goods. Selectorate theory (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003) explains that democracies avoid certain kinds of conflicts (i.e. ones they think they would have a hard time winning) because winning conflicts can be considered delivering on public goods. One may also think of the issues at stake in conflicts as corresponding to goods (either public or private). A government’s ability to win a conflict in a certain issue area may be seen as providing a public good or some share of private goods (beyond the regular public good of national security). If a conflict is salient enough, democratic publics may view repression during conflict as part of delivering the good of security (domestically as well as internationally), and thus may actually support the increase of repression against certain groups of the population. The mechanism at work here is not the conflict or issue of the conflict itself per se, but rather that the salience of it may lead to a public sense of insecurity that leads to at least tacit approval of increased repression (likely against minority groups seen as fifth columns or those opposed to the conflict effort of the state). We may expect this mechanism to be present when democracies increase repression in general, not just during interstate conflict. Other instances that might lead to acute and generalized sense of insecurity, such as after natural disasters (Wood and Wright, 2016), may also lead to a similar dynamic. But conflict may be a likely scenario in which we observe this mechanism at work.
Of the three conflict issues described above, victory in territorial conflict seems most likely to correspond to a “public” good. Although Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003) emphasize the private nature of territory—seeing it as resources that can be distributed to a leader’s supporters—there are numerous reasons to think territorial salience is more complex and will contain multiple aspects that are salient to various groups for different reasons. Contested territory can be tied to all manner of intangible qualities that make it salient in a very public way (Hensel and Mitchell, 2005). Especially if territory can be tied to national identity or has some symbolic value, it becomes something that is not easily divisible. This can engender in a public a feeling of urgency around winning a conflict that other issues may not (as easily) provide. Thus, a public may be willing to go along with repression in the name of victory and the provision of the contested territory-as-public good. If there are groups tied to the “other” in the conflict, they may be particularly vulnerable to repression, as might groups opposed to the conflict. Policy and regime conflicts seem less likely to strike at the heart of a sense of public welfare the same way as territory. Aside from being more escalatory than other conflict issues (Vasquez and Henehan, 2001), territorial conflicts may also lead to greater in-group/out-group identification among the public (Hutchison and Gibler, 2007; Gibler, Hutchison and Miller, 2012). This should lead to a rallying effect around a government pursuing territorial competition abroad. Furthermore, Miller (2013) finds the citizenry in states that initiate territorial disputes are happier overall. Wright (2014) argues the public value of contested territory can drive repression domestically for democracies, finding that as territorial revisionist years become more deadly for democracies, they become increasingly likely to increase repression.
Although we know from prior research that democracies repress less than autocracies, in general there is no reason to think democratic publics would never support the use of repression by their governments. Indeed, when security concerns are paramount, publics become less tolerant of so-called “others” and may be more willing to support increased human rights abuse in the name of national security. Wallace (2013) finds experimental evidence among a sample of Americans, that people are more willing to support the use of torture against enemy combatants. Although Wallace finds a mitigating impact of international law prompts, a noticeable percentage (nearly 40%) of his samples still support the use of torture against enemy combatants. Conrad, Hill, and Moore (2017) find that different democratic institutions may lead to differing incentives for leaders to engage in certain types of torture. Conrad, Hill, and Moore (2017) describe a model of electoral democracies in which the public becomes more likely to support the increase of the use of torture, in part because of the public pressure on governments, noting that states that allow dissent openly are also more likely to experience “challenges to state authority in the form of crime, protest and terror, producing greater demand among the voting public” (Conrad, Hill and Moore, 2017; 4) to increase punishment against such bad actors, including torture.6 This is in contrast to autocratic states, where anti-state activity is more routinely cracked down against, and thus unlikely to see more public outcry for punishment.
Democracies are more likely to increase repression during territorial conflict when they are the revisionists in conflict. Although it seems plausible that states might increase repression when they are the ones defending the status quo of territory, I believe the revisionist states likely find the issue dimension more salient because they are the ones seeking change. Furthermore, it is plausible that revisionist states likely would need to secure an outright victory in disputes to achieve their territorial goals, whereas status quo states may only need to secure a stalemate to preserve the status quo. Thus, the issue of the contested territory may not be as resonant with the status quo state as the revisionist state. Thus, a government will be more likely to do what they can to win, including increasing repression against groups seen to be a hindrance to that effort, whether fifth columns or opposition. If, as Miller (2013) argues and finds, territorial initiators have happier citizens, the public may also be more supportive of leadership in general and thus more supportive of policies aimed at securing the contested territory. In other words, if repression occurs as the result of pursuing territory abroad, the public is likely to be supportive of it. Because of the public good nature of territory and the way competition over it translates rallying to support a government, I argue that democratic revisionists in territorial conflicts will become more likely to increase repression. I note there is research that emphasizes democracies should be less likely to contest territory (Gibler, 2012). My argument does not contest this notion, only noting that despite territorial revisionism by democracies being rarer than by autocracies, it is more likely to lead to increased repression by democracies when it does occur.
Hypothesis 1. Democracies become more likely to increase repression when they are revisionists in territorial conflicts.

Expectations for autocratic states

Autocratic regimes rely on the distribution of private goods to an elite group of supporters to maintain leadership. Repression, which keeps those outside of the winning coalition from mobilizing, is a normal practice of governance (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003). Along this line of thought, as long as the government can provide a consistent (or increasing) distribution of private goods to their support coalition, they should be able to stave off threats to their authority. International conflict can act as an exogenous shock to their distributive capacity, however. Like economic sanctions, which squeeze the resources available for autocrats to distribute (Wood, 2008), pursuing international conflict costs military resources and money to pursue. This could leave them with fewer resources available for distribution and make leaders vulnerable to internal challenges. As a result, one might expect, in general, autocratic states would be likely to increase repression when involved in conflict abroad.
That said, such a likelihood increase seems unlikely to be the same across all conflicts. Autocratic leaders often have a great amount of choice in the conflicts they pursue (Chiozza and Goemans, 2011; Huth and Allee, 2002). Although not all autocracies have uniform levels of policy-making freedom and face varying levels of domestic constraint (Weeks, 2014), they do have similar concerns that distinguish them from democracies. First, public opinion is not such a major constraining force for autocratic leaders, and they are more reliant on the distribution of private goods to a smaller group than the public (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003). Another distinguishing factor, emphasized especially by Chiozza and Goemans (2011), is that they are more likely to be removed in an irregular fashion, via coup, assassination, or arrest. This threat of irregular removal and what happens to leaders after such removals can be a major motivating force for involvement in conflict abroad. Repression is a standard policy through which autocratic leaders maintain control and power (Davenport, 2007c). Thus it is likely such states would take the opportunity in certain international conflicts to solidify control via increased repression. Certain conflicts will be more likely than others to provide such opportunities. I contend that more than the other issues, policy disputes can provide such opportunities and may be more likely to be domestically motivated than conflicts over other issues.
Whereas policy conflicts actually cover a number of different particular policies, as discussed by Diehl (2013), these are disputes fought to stop another state from pursuing certain foreign policy practices (Jones et al., 1996). An example of this is when, in 2001, China downed a United States (US) spy plane to response to US reconnaissance practices (Militarized Interstate Dispute 4280). Another example, from the same year, is China displaying shows of force in the Taiwan Strait in response to perceived Tawainese moves toward independence. This dispute resulted in shows of force by both China and the US by conducting naval exercises in the area. These are two seemingly very different reasons for engaging in disputes, despite two of same disputants. Both are coded as policy disputes. Because of the variance in potential reasons for disputes being coded as “policy” disputes, it can be daunting to come up with a precise expectation of how autocratic states might generally respond to repression. Such conflicts may be prime examples that fit a “gambling” foreign policy strategy, as described by Chiozza and Goemans (2011).
These are conflicts that may be less likely to escalate to war and do not concern (in general) existential issues (such as territorial integrity or the survival of the regime itself) (Vasquez and Henehan, 2001). They may therefore not face the squeeze in military resources (which can be used for repression) that potentially escalatory conflicts such as those over territory may lead to. In which case, conflict involvement may have diversionary incentives (Pickering and Kisangani, 2010). Thus, these conflicts may be an opportunity to shore up support from the elite and leaders may also take the opportunity to increase repression. From this argument, there also seems to be likely to be no difference in the motivation for repression for whether an autocratic state is revisionist in a policy dispute. Thus, policy conflict involvement seems the most likely issue in which autocratic states would increase repression.
Not all policy disputes are of the kind described above, however. Unlike disputes over spy planes or naval exercises, some policy disputes are much more domestically focused. Salehyan (2009) argues that ongoing civil conflict processes influence the likelihood of international conflict via the presence of external rebel bases. The hosting of a rebel base can lead to interstate conflict. Examining the case narratives from 1993–1999 (the years for which Salehyan (2009, 110–113) provides narrative analysis and for which the Correlates of War (COW) provides dispute narratives), I found that of the disputes that had a revision type and were tied to the presence of rebels in one country or another, all but three were coded as having a policy revision at stake.7 I believe such disputes will have direct consequences for the level of domestic repression. Such a possibility is accounted for by Chiozza and Goemans (2011) as well. They note that such international conflicts are direct opportunities to harm violent opposition directly to strengthen the state’s leadership politically. Trumbore further finds that states experiencing rebellion are more likely to use force abroad (Trumbore, 2003). Increased domestic repression would logically increase as a result of such pursuits of rebels across borders and the states that host them.
For this described dynamic of using international conflict as an opportunity to increase domestic support via repression, territorial conflict seems a less likely issue for this to occur than policy disputes. Territorial conflict may be equally salient for autocratic states as democratic states, but potentially for a different reason. Territory, in addition to its symbolic or intangible value, may also present an opportunity for resource grabs by states. Because of the potential private goods gain from taking territory, autocratic revisionists may find such conflicts very salient. But conflicts over territory are also the most likely to escalate to war. So although they may present an opportunity for an autocrat to strengthen their leadership position by taking more resources that can be used for private good distribution, they may also have to pour more military resources into the conflict to acquire those goods. Indeed, Gibler (2012) notes that the pursuit of territorial competition abroad may require building up of military capacity and the use of land armies. Whereas in the long term, this may provide larger militaries that can be repressive during peace time (or after the conflict is over), during periods of territorial conflict itself these military resources may have to be spent abroad, leaving a lower repressive capacity at home. As a result, autocratic states may not become more repressive during territorial conflict. When examining the effect of territorial revisionism on repression, Wright (2014) finds that autocratic states actually become less likely to increase repression as they experience more deadly territorial-revisonist conflicts, lending credence to the idea that as more resources are used in high-stakes conflicts, repressive capacity may diminish, at least in the short term. The above discussion about how autocracies approach territorial and policy conflicts differently yields the following key hypothesis:
Hypothesis 2. Autocracies become more likely to increase repression when they are revisionists in policy conflicts.
The mechanisms underlying the increase in repression by democracies and autocracies in different issue conflicts are not the issues themselves, per se, but rather what the issues’ salience potentially represents to the leadership and key audiences of the different regime types. For democracies, increases in repression likely occur with at least tacit public backing, such as when the country as a whole feels threatened, because democratic leadership requires public backing to maintain itself. Territorial conflicts, although more rarely participated in by democracies, are more likely to be salient at a national-identity level than more narrowly focused policy conflicts. In contrast, although autocrats may have public backing for their repressive output, I would argue that for them to increase repression during conflict above already (likely) high levels of repression, it would need to be a salient threat to the regime’s ability to maintain its support with elites. Many policy conflicts may involve transnational rebel groups, which may specifically target autocratic regimes and thus present a more direct and salient threat to an autocratic leadership. Because the issues themselves are not direct analogues to the mechanisms themselves (public backing for repression or threats to the regime), I am only positing a probabilistic relationship between the issue type of international conflict and repression dynamics.

Research design

My theoretical focus is comparing the behavior of democratic and autocratic states. Because of this, I must choose a sample based on regime type. To do this, I rely on a dichotomous measure of regime type, employing the cutoff that is common in quantitative conflict research of six or above on the Polity scale for democracies, with all other states being coded as autocratic (Marshall and Jaggers, 2002).8 I incorporate 1 year lags on regime type variables. The Polity dataset assigns its values according to a country’s status on 31 December of the year for which it is assigned. Thus, by lagging the value 1 year, I am employing the value for 1 January of the year of the observation. Furthermore, it is in keeping in common practice to lag structural variables such as regime type, economic development, and population 1 year in repression studies (see Wood (2008) for an example). My samples include 1970 democratic years and 2195 autocratic country-years.
To test the above hypotheses, I test the effects of involvement in international conflict over various issues on state repression. I employ the Cingranelli and Richards’ (2010) scale of physical integrity rights. It measures respect for rights in a state by counting the number of abuse events across four behaviors: imprisonment, torture, killing, and disappearances. For coding personal integrity rights, these data rely on both the US State Department annual Human Rights reports as well as the Amnesty International annual reports as source material. It is a standards-based, ordered, scaled index measure where 0 is no respect measured as 50 or more violations in a year, one is between one and 49 violations, and two is no violations recorded that year. Summing the level of respect across the four behaviors, the combined scale produces a 0–8 scale, where lower scores are more repressive. In keeping with common practice of studying repression, I have reversed the scale, so that higher numbers are more repressive. I have chosen to employ the Cingranelli and Richards (CIRI) data in this project, as opposed to other human rights data such as the Political Terror Scale (Wood and Gibney, 2010), primarily because it has the ability to break down physical integrity violations into their component behaviors. As such, my analysis contains models of all five CIRI outcomes: political imprisonment, torture, disappearances, killings, and the additive scale. This allows for a logical extension of my hypotheses to investigate which behaviors different regime types might focus on. This approach to analyzing the various components of CIRI has been employed in prior research as well (Cingranelli and Filppov, 2010).
Because my dependent variables are all ordered scales, I employ ordered probit analyses. In keeping with common practice for quantitative studies of human rights using a similarly scaled dependent variable (see Wood (2008) for an example), I employ a series of binary lags of the dependent variable categories. After accounting for missing data, my sample is 2195 autocratic countries from the years of 1982–2010.
My key independent variables involvement in international conflict across three different issue areas, and whether a state was a revisionist in such a conflict in a given year. For conflict issue, I rely on the Militarized Interstate Dispute (MID) 4.01 (participant) data (Palmer et al., 2015). I code each state’s involvement in a given year based on their primary revision type coding,9 and whether they were an originating state (involved on the first day of the conflict). Militarized interstate disputes range from the threat of the use of force all the way through conflicts that reach war (which is 1000 battle deaths). The correlates of war project coded states as revisionists if they attempt to alter the status quo in one of three issue areas: territory, policy, and regime. I should note that revisionists are not necessarily initiators of conflict, but simply the states involved in a dispute who wish to alter the status quo along some issue dimension. Disputes may have multiple revisionists along differing issues. In bilateral conflicts as well, both states can be revisionists seeking to alter the status quo of the other (Jones et al., 1996; Ghosn et al., 2004). For instance, in the conflict over the Nagorno-Karabakh region between Armenia and Azerbaijan, for which the MID data codes from 1992–1995,10 both states are coded as revisionists (Saideman and Ayres, 2008; Laitin and Suny, 1999). According to Jones, Bremer, and Singer (1996), revisionists in territorial conflict seek to alter the territorial status quo by the taking of disputed land or rivers or maritime areas. Policy revisionists are concerned with altering the foreign policy practices of another state. Regime revisionists’ goal is to remove the regime of the status quo state. Furthermore, these are not mutually exclusive categories for any given country-year. A state can appear revisionist or non-revisionist in the same years across issue types. This is most appropriate because I am gauging whether, on average, revisionism of a particular type is associated with more repression.
For revisionists’ participation, I chose to exclude non-originating participants because conflict joiners may have very different motivation for involvement in conflict than the issue at stake for originating revisionists. The MID data also include a fourth category of “other” for disputes for which the revision type does not fit into any of the other categories. To account for participation in these conflicts, for conflict participation as only a “status quo” state, as well as conflicts in which a state might join the conflict later as an ally to an originating state, I control for participation in any militarized dispute in a given year. After accounting for the revisionist MID years in disputes for those issues, as well as years in which any MID occurred, the comparison group will be years in which the state did not participate in a MID in any way.
For additional control variables, I include population (logged, lagged), economic development (as measured by the logged, lagged amount of gross domestic product (GDP)), and involvement in a civil war. Good economic performance is seen to improve a government’s strength relative to political threat, and thus high GDP should be associated with less repression, whereas states with high populations have been found to be more repressive (Poe and Tate, 1994; Poe et al., 1999). The data for economic development and population are taken from Gleditsch (2002). Civil war is associated, almost by definition, with more repression because it involves directly engaging militarily with elements from a domestic population (Davenport, 2007b). Civil wars are coded from the intensity variable in the Uppsala Conflict Data Project for whether a state was engaged in a civil war, 1000 or more battle deaths, in a given year (Gleditsch et al., 2002).11 Because I am interested in how conflict leads to shifts in repressive behavior from 1 year to the next, I lag the structural variables (population, and economic development), which is a common practice among repression studies (see, for a recent example, Wood (2008)). I do not lag civil war or international conflict involvement because they may immediately impact the repressive output of states.

Results

Because my hypotheses are conditional on regime type, I chose to split the sample according to regime type. Although theoretically motivated, I also did this in lieu of a large interaction model to make interpretation simpler.12 In Table 1, I present results of ordered probit models on state repression by democratic states, and below that I present the results for the autocratic sample in Table 2.
Table 1. International conflict issues and state repression: democratic sample, 1982–2010.
  (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
  CIRI scale Imprisonment Torture Killings Disappearances
Territorial revisionist 0.174** (0.084) 0.349** (0.171) 0.347*** (0.119) 0.224* (0.121) −0.172 (0.138)
Regime revisionist −0.127 (0.271) 0.126 (0.228) −0.232 (0.327) −0.003 (0.450) −0.641 (0.476)
Policy revisionist 0.138 (0.112) 0.243 (0.159) 0.104 (0.151) 0.309** (0.146) 0.091 (0.142)
Population (ln, t-1) 0.137*** (0.030) 0.147*** (0.036) 0.150*** (0.030) 0.159*** (0.041) 0.152*** (0.041)
GDP per capita (ln, t-1) −0.264*** (0.039) −0.284*** (0.048) −0.253*** (0.040) −0.299*** (0.051) −0.241*** (0.048)
Civil war 0.715*** (0.199) 0.396* (0.238) 0.451* (0.259) 0.881*** (0.183) 0.863*** (0.234)
Any MID 0.085 (0.065) 0.152* (0.088) 0.065 (0.080) −0.134 (0.098) 0.201 (0.129)
WaldX2 1044.87*** 794.49*** 431.83*** 542.04*** 337.65***
Panels 109 109 109 109 109
Observations 1970 1970 1970 1970 1970
Standard errors clustered on the country. Two-tailed significance: ***p|<| 0.01, **p|<| 0.05, *p|<| 0.1.
MID: Militarized Interstate Dispute; GDP: gross domestic product; CIRI: Cingranelli and Richards; ln: natural log; t-1: lagged one year.
Table 2. International conflict issues and state repression: autocratic sample, 1982–2010.
  (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
  CIRI scale Imprisonment Torture Killings Disappearances
Territorial revisionist −0.037 (0.111) 0.178 (0.135) 0.015 (0.176) −0.120 (0.106) −0.104 (0.157)
Regime revisionist 0.072 (0.147) 0.330 (0.203) 0.195 (0.229) −0.137 (0.195) −0.009 (0.148)
Policy revisionist 0.266*** (0.089) −0.050 (0.117) 0.282** (0.123) 0.382*** (0.124) 0.327*** (0.096)
Population (ln, t-1) 0.141*** (0.020) 0.139*** (0.034) 0.158*** (0.026) 0.147*** (0.022) 0.112*** (0.024)
GDP per capita (ln, t-1) −0.087*** (0.028) −0.005 (0.033) −0.083** (0.036) −0.184*** (0.035) −0.077** (0.036)
Civil war 0.638*** (0.096) 0.443*** (0.158) 0.253* (0.129) 0.799*** (0.126) 0.616*** (0.132)
Any MID 0.170*** (0.060) 0.224*** (0.076) 0.012 (0.084) 0.199*** (0.070) 0.178** (0.079)
Wald X2 1076.98*** 771.48*** 653.45*** 802.88*** 457.55***
Panels 122 122 122 122 122
Observations 2195 2195 2195 2195 2195
Standard errors clustered on the country. Two-tailed significance: ***p|<| 0.01, **p|<| 0.05, *p|<| 0.1.
MID: Militarized Interstate Dispute; GDP: gross domestic product; ln: natural log; t-1: lagged one year.
To begin with the analysis of the democratic sample, hypothesis 1 receives support. Territorial revisionism in MIDs has a statistically significant and positive relationship with repression for democratic states. As expected, no other type of conflict involvement has a statistically significant relationship with overall repression for democracies. Furthermore, territorial revisionism has a positive and significant impact on the use of imprisonment and torture, indicating that although democracies increase repression, they may not do so across all forms of repression. There is also a significant, and somewhat unexpected, relationship between policy revisionism and increases in imprisonment. Given that imprisonment is one of the more common forms of repression, perhaps this finding is not too surprising. Territorial revisionism appears to be the only type of interstate conflict that consistently leads to an increase in repression by democracies. Thus, in accordance with prior work exploring when democracies repress (Davenport, 2007b), it may be the forces that keep democracies less repressive are at work during periods of interstate conflict, and only fail to prevent increases in repression during particularly salient conflicts. Finally, in the democratic sample, the population, GDP, and civil war controls perform as expected.
Because coefficients from ordered probit analyses are not easily interpreted for substantive effects, in Figure 1 I have presented the predicted probabilities, calculated with CLARIFY software (King, Tomz, and Wittenberg, 2000), and 90% confidence intervals of a one category increase from the democracy modal category for overall repression (mode=1), imprisonment (mode=0) and torture (mode=1), given participation in a MID as a territorial revisionist. These are all significant as the mean value of the treated group (territorial revision=1) is outside the upper bound of confidence interval for the untreated group. In years for which democracies are not a territorial revisionist, their likelihood of reaching two on the CIRI scale is roughly 0.23, which increases to roughly 0.28 when they are territorial revisionists, an absolute increase of about 5% likelihood, for a relative increase of about 22%. The probability in the use of imprisonment goes from about 0.12 to about 0.24, for an absolute increase of about 12% and a relative increase of about 100%. For torture, the likelihood goes from 0.16 to about 0.28, for an absolute increase of 12% and a relative increase of roughly 75%. I have calculated first differences of these predicted probabilities and their 90% confidence intervals, which are not displayed to save space, and all of them are significant at the 0.10 level.
Figure 1. Likelihood of repression increases during territorial revision by democracies.
From simulations of Table 1, Models 1, 2, and 3. Prior-year DV values set at modal categories, with continuous controls set at their mean and all other values set at 0. This figure displays the predicted probability that a democratic state will reach level two on the CIRI, one on imprisonment, and two on the torture scales. Predicted probabilities were generated using CLARIFY software (King et al., 2000).
DV: dependent variable; CIRI: Cingranelli-Richards scale.
To further explore the above findings on democracies, territory and repression, the case of Ecuador in the mid-1990s is illustrative. Ecuador and Peru had a long-standing border dispute that was eventually settled in 1998 (Simmons, 1999). According to the COW’s militarized dispute narratives (MIDs 4013 and 4143) (Palmer et al., 2015), Ecuador and Peru engaged in multiple disputes starting in early 1995 (MID 4013), resuming later in 1995 and ending in October 1996 (MID 4143), with both states claiming border violations and uses of force by the other (COW, 2013). Both Ecuador and Peru are listed as a territorial revisionists for these disputes, Ecuador is democratic in the time period, Peru is not. According to the explanation, we are likely to observe the democratic Ecuador increasing repressive behaviors during this militarized dispute. According to the State Department report for Ecuador in 1995 (State Department, 1996, section 1.D.), there were politically motivated arrests of Peruvian nationals, specifically: “In the wake of hostilities with Peru in January and February, a number of Peruvian nationals were arrested by the military and the police on charges of espionage and detained for several months beyond the end of hostilities. The weak evidence presented against them left the Government open to charges that they were being detained arbitrarily. By July all had been released.” According to the data used above, Ecuador’s overall physical integrity score (reversed) score increases from two in 1994 to three in 1995, then four in 1996. Political imprisonment increases from a score a 0 to a maximum score of two in 1995. Torture increases in 1996 but not in 1995. For its part, autocratic Peru did not see in an increase in physical integrity violations in 1995, but actually saw a decrease from 1994 levels (from seven to five) before returning to its pre-MID levels (seven) in 1996. Both of these trends in the cases are in line with my expectations.
In Table 2, I present results of ordered probit models on state repression by autocratic states. Hypothesis 2 receives support. As expected, autocratic states are not more likely to increase repression during territorial conflicts. In line with expectations, there is a statistically significant and positive relationship between policy MID revisionism and increases in repression by autocratic states. Involvement in policy disputes leads to increases in the use of killing, disappearances, as well as torture, when autocrats are revisionists. That said, when autocrats are involved in policy disputes, they are unlikely to alter their use of imprisonment. This could be because autocracies have a relatively high baseline level of repression, the core behavior of which may be imprisonment. Thus, increases in tactics that are more severe than imprisonment are those most likely to change when autocratic states experience an exogenous shock to the political status quo. Finally, in the autocratic sample, the GDP, population, and civil war controls’ results were largely as expected. In line with prior work and expectations, economic development is negatively related to repression, whereas population and civil war involvement are positively related to repression across all types of repression for autocracies, with one exception. Economic development is unrelated, in this analysis, to the use of imprisonment by autocratic governments.
In Figure 2 I have presented the predicted probabilities, calculated with CLARIFY software (King et al., 2000), and 90% confidence intervals of a one category increase from the modal autocratic level of overall repression, torture, killings, and disappearances when they participate in MIDs as policy revisionists. For overall repression, the modal category is a four out of eight, and autocracies go from being about 0.17 likely to increase at level five to 0.23 when involved in a MID as a policy revisionist, a 35% relative increase. For disappearances, for which the mode is 0, they are likely to go from about a 0.12 likelihood to a roughly 0.23 likelihood, a relative increase of 92%. For torture, their likelihood of increase from the mode of one, goes from roughly 0.34 to 0.45, a relative increase of 32%. Finally, for killing, they increase from about 0.12 to 0.28, a relative increase in likelihood of over 100%. The first differences of these probabilities were also calculated and are all significant at the 0.10 level.
Figure 2. Likelihood of repression increases during policy revision by autocracies.
From simulations of Table 2, Models 1, 3, 4, and 5. Prior-year DV values set at modal categories, with continuous controls set at their mean and all other values set at 0. This figure displays the predicted probability that a democratic state will reach level five on the CIRI, 1 on disappearances, two on torture, and two on the killing scales. Predicted probabilities were generated using CLARIFY software.
To illustrate how policy disputes might lead to increased repressive practices by autocracies, the case of clashes between Eritrea and Sudan, as well as a dispute between Sudan and Uganda, in 1996 are helpful. In the first dispute between Eritrea and Sudan, both states increased their use of physical integrity violations in 1996 during which they also fought as policy revisionists against each other (MID 4124). The MID narrative (COW, 2013) notes that both sides accused each other of supporting opposition groups against the governments. Furthermore, Salehyan (2009, 112–113) notes that over 1996, Sudanese rebels launched attacked from Eritrea. Eritrea accused Sudan of supporting Islamic opposition in a plot to overthrow the Eritrean president. According to the US State Department reports for Eritrea and Sudan in 1996, both states engaged in repressive activities against opposition movements mentioned in the MID narrative (State Department, 1997a; 1997b). Specifically, in Eritrea “an unspecified number of persons associated with radical Islamic elements or suspected terrorist organizations also remained in detention without charge,” (State Department, 1997a, section 1D). In the data employed above, Eritrea moves from a physical integrity score of two in 1995 to four in 1996. Sudan is a much more repressive state during the period, going from a physical integrity score of six in 1995 to a maximum score of eight in 1996.
In addition to citing human rights violations along the Eritrean border relating to battles between the government and insurgencies (State Department, 1997b, section 1G), the State Department report also notes that “there were continued allegations that the Government was responsible for the arrest and subsequent disappearance of those suspected of supporting rebels in government-controlled zones of the south and the Nuba Mountains,” (State Department, 1997b, section 1B). These particular abuses may tie more to another policy dispute in which Sudan was engaged at the same time against Uganda. In this dispute (MID 4078), which lasted from 1994–1997, both states accuse each other of supporting rebel groups (COW, 2013). Uganda also increased its repression level during the conflict in both 1994 and 1996. Specifically, it increases the use of imprisonment in 1994 and both imprisonment and torture in 1996 compared to the prior year. Although specific abuses (use of imprisonment, torture, killings, and disappearances) by the state are not discussed in light of the clashes with Sudan, the State Department reports for both 1994 and 1996 for Uganda describe rebel movement by the Lord’s Resistance Army into Sudan (State Department, 1995; 1997c).
The above cases of Ecuador, Eritrea, Sudan, and Uganda are illustrative of some of the core dynamics described by my theoretical approach. First, when contesting territory, democratic Ecuador did increase its use of imprisonment of those suspected to be tied to the “other,” in this case Peruvian nationals. Second, the illustrations of how policy disputes may lead to increases in repression by autocratic states gives credence to the notion that at least some of these disputes are domestic in origin. All three countries increased repression during years in which they were policy revisionists in the pursuit of rebel groups operating in another country’s border. Although there is a great amount of variance in policy disputes, this particular path appears to be related to domestic repression and should be given more attention in work that more fully explores policy disputes.

Robustness checks, alternative explanations, and new questions

In addition to the above analyses, I have conducted several robustness checks, which are displayed in the online appendix to this article. Firstly, my above analyses split the sample according to regime type. I did this because theoretically I am arguing that democracies and autocracies have different processes for making decisions to repress and different reasons for engaging in conflict abroad. I also did this for ease of interpretation. Another route would have been to pool the full sample of observations and interact conflict issue with regime type. I conducted analyses along these lines and the results are substantively similar, with one exception. In the full sample analysis, the interaction between democracies and territorial revision is not significant in predicting imprisonment. Beyond this analysis, I also conducted a full sample interaction model including civil conflict at a lower threshold (25 or more deaths) and found substantively similar results.
My theoretical conception of regime type is dichotomous. In my abstract set up, the leadership of states is elected and accountable to the general public or subject to the whims of a small elite (Bueno de Mesquita et al., 2003). As such, I employed a commonly used dichotomous measure of democracy, a cutoff of six or higher on the Polity scale (Marshall and Jaggers, 2002). To explore the veracity of the above findings, I conducted additional analyses employing the Varieties of Democracy’s liberal democracy and electoral democracy (polyarchy) measures (Coppedge et al., 2016). I analyzed the full sample, interacting either the liberal democracy or polyarchy with conflict revision type, and found largely similar results to those above. The results employing the electoral democracy (polyarchy) variable are closest to those present into the main results, which should not be too surprising given the rather minimalist conception of democracy employed. The results employing the liberal democracy variable found significant results between the interaction of territorial revision and liberal democracy on the overall repression scale as well as for killing, which is surprising. The results of these robustness checks underscore the need for future research exploring the linkage between conflict behavior, repression, and different aspects of democratic states’ institutions.
In addition to the above concerns, one of the major potential questions that these above results raise is the degree to which the domestic repression and international conflict have reverse causation. In other words, does the increase (or as yet unobserved need for an increase) in repression lead to the onset of international conflict in the first place? Are the states that are more repressive the ones engaging in the conflicts that correlate to a subsequent increase in repression?
Although these questions are related to my study, they are somewhat beyond the scope of my analysis, because it is not taking on the question of conflict selection. That said, one way to try and get at this is to see if more repressive states are driving the findings that I observe above. To do that I ran additional models based on my primary analyses above (Table 1, Model 1; Table 2, Model 1). In these analyses, I interact the value for prior-year repression, included as a control above, with territorial revisionism for the democratic sample and interact prior repression with policy revisionism in the autocratic sample. I display these results in Table 3 below.
Table 3. International conflict issues and state repression: interacting prior repression with conflict, 1982–2010.
  (1) (2)
  CIRI CIRI
  Democratic sample Autocratic sample
Territorial revisionist 0.484*** (0.168) −0.049 (0.105)
Regime revisionist −0.126 (0.272) 0.057 (0.150)
Policy revisionist 0.152 (0.112) −0.180 (0.282)
CIRI (t-1) X territorial revisionist −0.088** (0.034)  
CIRI (t-1) X policy revisionist   0.082# (0.051)
Population (ln, t-1) 0.139*** (0.029) 0.142*** (0.020)
GDP per capita (ln, t-1) −0.266*** (0.039) −0.089*** (0.028)
Civil war 0.736*** (0.205) 0.638*** (0.097)
Any MID 0.074 (0.064) 0.179*** (0.060)
Wald Chi-squared 1175.28*** 1079.04***
Panels 109 122
Observations 1970 2195
Coefficient for prior repression included but not displayed. Prior repression at both the lower order and multiplicative term is measured as the CIRI scale, rather than a series of binary lags in order to ease interpretation. Standard errors clustered on the country. Two-tailed significance: ***p|<| 0.01, **p|<| 0.05, *p|<| 0.1. #p 0.129.
MID: Militarized Interstate Dispute; GDP: gross domestic product; CIRI: Cingranelli and Richards; ln: natural log; t-1: lagged one year.
The results in Table 3 are suggestive that the more repressive states might drive the above findings only in the autocratic sample. In Model 1, for the democratic sample, we see the lower order term on territorial revisionism as statistically significant and positive, which means the least repressive democratic states are still likely to increase repression when revisionists in territorial MIDs. This suggests territorial MIDs are one of the rare “shocks” (when compared with autocracies) that lead to democratic states to increase repression. For the autocratic sample, however, neither the lower order term on policy revision nor the interaction term are statistically significant. The interaction term is positive and approaches one-tailed significance with a p value of 0.129. This suggests that more repressive autocracies might be increasing repression during policy MIDs.
The finding that more repressive autocracies are more repressive during conflict is perhaps not too surprising, given the research on the linkages between repression, civil conflict, and international conflict onset. Trumbore (2003) finds that states experiencing rebellion are more likely to engage in conflicts abroad, whereas Caprioli and Trumbore (2006) find that more repressive states are more likely to be involved in international conflicts. Beyond this, if policy MIDs really do contain more rebel chases, as the narratives of Salehyan’s (2009) cases suggest, then the findings for both my analysis in Table 2 and Table 3 are being driven by these cases. In other words, autocratic states experiencing rebellion (a direct threat to the elites and regime) are more likely to be repressive. When these rebellions lead to conflict abroad, these international conflicts also coincide with these increases in repression. These connected findings are all consistent with well understood mechanisms leading to autocratic repression.
To more fully explore the above question, one would need to explore jointly the processes of domestic repression and international conflict selection. This would need to likely incorporate an analysis of interstate conflict opponent in addition to modeling repressive targets. This is beyond the scope of the current project, but there is suggestive evidence that such a pursuit would be worthwhile.

Conclusion

Does international conflict involvement affect domestic repression? In short, yes. I argue that in contrast to prior work, how interstate conflict affects domestic repression is a function of the issue of the conflict and role of states. These results imply a number of conclusions. First, international conflict affects domestic repression, but does so in ways more complicated than prior treatments, which included a dummy variable for international war participation, could reveal. These results identify different pathways that conflict abroad leads to repression at home.
I argue that the salience of a conflict will vary by issue according to the domestic political needs of leaders. Democratic governments, which rely on public goods provision to maintain office, will be more likely to find territorial conflict especially salient. Because contested territory can tap into intangible (and therefore not easily divisible) ties such as to national identity or have high symbolic value, the general public may be willing to support somewhat extreme measures to achieve victory. As a result, I argue it is most likely that democracies will increase repression when involved in international conflict as territorial revisionists, which are those states that are seeking to take territory, compared to involvement in international disputes over policy or regime. I have found empirical support for this prediction.
Although autocratic states do not appear to be more likely to increase repression during territorial conflicts, they are more likely to do so when engaged in interstate disputes over policy. Policy disputes are much more common than territorial disputes, and although they are not as likely to escalate to war (Vasquez and Henehan, 2001), these results imply that they can be very dangerous domestically for the countries involved. This article makes some theoretical and empirical progress toward better understanding interstate policy disputes, but, like Diehl (2013), I contend that much more work in this area needs to be done on unpacking policy and regime disputes, specifically investigating the linkage between these issue areas and transnational rebellion (Salehyan, 2009). That the majority of Salehyan’s (2009) case narratives of disputes for which there was a revision type are policy disputes, and because such disputes are tied to domestic repression by autocracies, indicates the roots of many such disputes may be more domestically oriented than international.
Another direction for future research is to examine the domestic effects of conflict by different types of autocracies. Recent research by Jessica Weeks (2014) has laid the groundwork for treating autocratic states as non-homogenous. Weeks’ work shows the relationship between leaders and their key constituencies may greatly affect international conflict bargaining. We should therefore expect that international conflict may also affect these different autocratic type’s propensity for repression differently. This project was more focused on the differences among issues in conflict, and thus various regime types of autocracies was outside the scope. Some repression research has investigated different types of autocratic states (Davenport, 2007c), the interaction between lower levels of international conflict and autocratic regime type could use more attention.
Furthermore, the analysis reveals which types of repression states are likely to employ in conflict contexts. Autocracies, during policy conflicts, appear to increase more violent forms of repression in torture and killings, but not imprisonment. This could be because imprisonment is relatively commonplace in autocratic states, regardless of whether they are involved in conflicts. Although there is some prior and ongoing work that breaks down the various repressive behaviors (Piazza and Walsh, 2009; Cingranelli and Filppov, 2010), which attempts to theoretically and empirically understand the degree to which these behaviors are related to one another, it is under-researched compared to studies of overall levels of repression. The results from the present analysis may help shed some light on these questions.
More broadly, these results imply that across conflict issues, there are different levels of salience for domestic political behavior. This project opens up the “black box” of militarized interstate dispute participation according to issue area, which is but one way that international conflict might be more closely examined. Other behaviors beyond repression, such as civil liberty restrictions (Davenport, 2004; 2007b), might also be differentially affected by different kinds of conflict involvement. Future research should further explore issues when considering the domestic impacts of international conflict. Understanding more precisely in which conflicts states might differ in their repressive responses is useful, not only from a knowledge-gathering perspective, but also from a policy standpoint. The findings highlight once again that autocracies are generally worse for human rights, especially when they are involved in international policy disputes that may be less dangerous in terms of the likelihood of war, but more dangerous for human rights domestically. Thus, despite perhaps a seemingly routine nature of policy disputes, they may lead to increases in repression domestically, and activists should be mindful when such disputes occur.

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank Dan Berliner, Jacqueline Demeritt, Chris Fariss, Amanda Murdie, and Reed Wood for helpful comments and suggestions. I would also like to thank IASR editor Scott Gates and reviewers for their suggestions. All statistical analyses were performed using STATA, version 14.2.

Author note

An early version of this paper was presented at the 2013 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, 29 August to 1 September, Chicago, Illinois.

Conflict of Interest

The author declares that there is no conflict of interest.

Funding

The author received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

ORCID iD

Footnotes

1. A similar way of theoretically organizing environmental factors’ impact on civil and international conflict is to describe long-term predictors as “trends” and short-term predictors as “triggers” (Hendrix and Glaser, 2007; Devlin and Hendrix, 2014). This is also similar to viewing a state’s repression as a punctuated equilibrium (Baumgartner and Jones, 1991; Diehl and Goertz, 2000).
2. That said, Fariss (2014) finds that human rights respect has gradually improved over time, across the world, and that data may not be picking up this trend because standards have increased as well.
3. There is a rich literature on why territorial conflict is the most likely to escalate to war and the domestic importance of territory, but I do not wish to labor the point here. The most up-to-date review of this work is by Gibler (2012).
4. Work by Gibler (2007; 2012) suggests the “stable border peace” may actually supplant democratic peace, at least in dyads that are contiguous, although the work by Owsiak (2012) finds the democratic peace finding is robust. See also work by Gibler and Owsiak (2018).
5. In my sample for instance, there are 526 observations of policy revisionist-years, compared to only 57 regime revisionist-years.
6. Conrad et al. (2017) also distinguish which democratic mechanisms lead to differing levels of use of different types of torture. This project only examines the use of torture, in general, however.
7. Salehyan (2009, 111) lists 23 dyadic disputes in which external bases were present the year the militarized dispute began and for which there was a MID narrative provided by the COW. On examination of the narratives, Salehyan found that four were not related to the external bases. Of the remaining 19 that were tied to the bases, another four did not have a revision typed coded in the militarized interstate dispute data (Palmer et al., 2015). Of the 15 remaining that did have a revision type coded, one was coded as a territorial dispute, and two others had a regime revisionist coding as their primary revision types. In total, 12 of the 15 disputes had at least one dyadic participant as a primarily policy revisionist.
8. I also conducted robustness checks with the Varieties of Democracies’ (V-Dem, version 8) “liberal democracy” and “polyarchy” measure (Coppedge et al., 2016; Coppedge et al., 2018). The findings are substantively similar to what I display and are included in the online appendix.
9. On some disputes, the data record a secondary revision type (Kenwick et al., 2014). I chose to exclude these and focus solely on the primary issue as the one driving the dispute. Because I am comparing across several different issues, this seemed the most prudent and clearest decision. If a participant is coded has having a secondary revision on territory, for instance, they would have some other issue as the primary, which would lead to double-counting.
10. Although the conflict began before this, the COW only codes Armenia and Azerbaijan’s current statehood as beginning in the early 1990s.
11. I have also conducted robustness checks with lower-levels of civil conflict (25 battle deaths) and found substantively similar results.
12. That said, I have conducted tests employing the full sample with variables interacting democracy and involvement in different types of MIDs. The results are substantively similar to those presented in Tables 1 and 2.

References

Baumgartner FR, Jones BD (1991) Agenda dynamics and policy subsystems. Journal of Politics 53: 1044–1074.
Bueno de Mesquita B, Smith A, Siverson RM, et al. (2003) The Logic of Political Survival. Boston: The MIT Press.
Bueno de Mesquita B, Downs GW, Smith A, et al. (2005) Thinking inside the box: A closer look at democracy and human rights. International Studies Quarterly 49: 439–457.
Caprioli M, Trumbore PF (2006) Human rights rogues in interstate disputes, 1980–2001. Journal of Peace Research 43: 131–148.
Chiozza G, Goemans H (2011) Leaders and International Conflict. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Cingranelli DL, Richards DL (2010) The Cingranelli and Richards (CIRI) Human Rights Data Project. Human Rights Quarterly 32: 401–424.
Cingranelli D, Filppov M (2010) Electoral rules and incentives to protect human rights. Journal of Politics 72: 243–257.
Conrad CR, Hill DW, Moore WH (2017) Torture and the limits of democratic institutions. Journal of Peace Research online first:1–15.
Coppedge M, Lindberg SI, Skanning SE, et al. (2018) V-Dem Codebook v8. Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project. https://doi.org/10.23696/vdemcy18.
Coppedge M, Lindberg SI, Skaaning SE, et al. (2016) Measuring high level democratic principles using the V-Dem Data. International Political Science Review 37: 580–593.
COW, Correlates of War (2013) Dispute Narratives, 1993–2001. Correlates of War Project, MIDv4.0 Project. Available at: http://www.correlatesofwar.org/data-sets/MIDs (accessed 2 July 2015)
Davenport C (1995) Multi-dimensional threat perception and state repression: An inquiry into why states apply negative sanctions. American Journal of Political Science 39: 683–713.
Davenport C (2004) The promise of democratic pacification: An empirical assessment. International Studies Quarterly 48: 539–560.
Davenport C (2007a) State repression and political order. Annual Review of Political Science 10:1–23.
Davenport C (2007b) State Repression and the Domestic Democratic Peace. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Davenport C (2007c) State repression and the tyrannical peace. Journal of Peace Research 44: 485–504.
Davenport C, Armstrong DA (2004) Democracy and the violation of human rights: A statistical analysis from 1976–1996. American Journal of Political Science 48: 538–554.
Devlin C, Hendrix CS (2014) Trends and triggers redux: Climate change, rainfall, and interstate conflict. Political Geography forthcoming 43: 27–39.
Diehl PF (1992) What are they fighting for? The importance of issues in international conflict research. Journal of Peace Research 29: 333–344.
Diehl PF (2013) J David Singer and conflict issues: Does it matter over what states fight? International Studies Review 15: 265–270.
Diehl PF, Goertz G (2000) War and Peace in Enduring Rivalry. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Fariss CJ (2014) Respect for human rights has improved over time: Modeling the changing standard of accountability. American Political Science Review 108: 297–318.
Ghosn F, Palmer G, Bremer S (2004) The MID 3 Data Set, 1993–2001: Procedures, coding rules, and description. Conflict Management and Peace Science 21: 133–154.
Gibler DM (2007) Bordering on peace: Democracy, territorial issues, and conflict. International Studies Quarterly 51: 509–532.
Gibler DM (2010) Outside-in: External the effects of external threat on state centralization. Journal of Conflict Resolution 54: 519–542.
Gibler DM (2012) The Territorial Peace: Borders, State Development, and International Conflict. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Gibler DM, Owsiak A (2018) Democracy and the settlement of international borders, 1919–2001. Journal of Conflict Resolution 62: 1847–1875.
Gibler DM, Hutchison ML, Miller SV (2012) Individual identity attachments and international conflict: The importance of territorial threat. Comparative Political Studies 45: 1655–1683.
Gleditsch KS (2002) Expanded trade and GDP data. Journal of Conflict Resolution 46: 712–724.
Gleditsch KS, Salehyan I, Schultz K (2008) Fighting at home, fighting abroad: How civil wars lead to international disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution 52: 479–506.
Gleditsch NP, Wallensteen P, Eriksson M, et al. (2002) Armed conflict, 1946–2001: A new dataset. Journal of Peace Research 39: 615–637.
Goddard SE (2006) Uncommon ground: Indivisible territory and the politics of legitimacy. International Organization 60: 35–68.
Hafner-Burton EM (2014) A social science of human rights. Journal of Peace Research 51: 273–286.
Hendrix CS, Glaser SM (2007) Trends and triggers: Climate, climate change, and civil conflict in Sub-Saharan Africa. Political Geography 26: 695–715.
Hensel PR, McLaughlin Mitchell S (2005) Issue indivisibility and territorial claims. GeoJournal 64: 275–85.
Hill DW Jr, Jones ZM (2014) An empirical evaluation of explanations for state repression. American Political Science Review 108: 661–687.
Hutchison ML, Gibler DM (2007) Political tolerance and territorial threat: A cross-national study. Journal of Politics 69: 128–142.
Huth PK, Allee T (2002) The Democratic Peace and Territorial Conflict in the Twentieth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jones DM, Bremer SA, Singer JD (1996) Militarized interstate disputes, 1816–1992: Rationale, coding rules, and empirical patterns. Conflict Management and Peace Science. 15: 163–213.
Kenwick MR, Lane M, Ostick B, et al. (2014) Codebook for the Militarized Interstate Dispute Data, Version 4.0. Pennsylvania State University: www.correlatesofwar.org.
King G, Tomz M, Wittenberg J (2000) Making the most of statistical analyses: Improving interpretation and presentation. American Journal of Political Science 44: 347–361.
Laitin DD, Suny RG (1999) Armenia and Azerbaijan: Thinking a way out of Karabakh. Middle East Policy 7: 145–176.
Mansbach RW, Vasquez JA (1981) The effect of actor and issue classifications on the analysis of global conflict-cooperation. Journal of Politics 43: 861–874.
Marshall M, Jaggers K (2002) Polity IV Project: Dataset User’s Manual. University of Maryland: Polity IV Project.
Miller SV (2013) Territorial disputes and the politics of individual well-being. Journal of Peace Research 50: 677–690.
Owsiak AP (2012) Signing up for peace: International boundary agreements, democracy, and militarized interstate conflict. International Studies Quarterly 56: 51–66.
Owsiak AP (2013) Democratization and international border agreements. Journal of Politics 75: 717–729.
Palmer G, D’Arazio V, Kenwick M, et al. (2015) The MID4 Dataset, 2002–2010: Procedures, coding rules, and description. Conflict Management and Peace Science 32: 222–242.
Piazza JA, Walsh JI (2009) Transnational terror and human rights. International Studies Quarterly 53: 125–148.
Pickering J, Kisangani EF (2010) Diversionary despots? Comparing autocracies’ propensities to use and to benefit from military force. American Journal of Political Science 54: 477–493.
Poe SC (2004) The decision to repress. In Understanding Human Rights Violations: New Systematic Studies, ed. Poe SC, Carey S. United Kingdom, Ashgate Press.
Poe SC, Tate CN (1994) Repression of human rights to personal integrity in the 1980s: A global analysis. American Political Science Review 88: 853–72.
Poe SC, Tate CN, Camp Keith L (1999) Repression of the human right to personal integrity revisited: A global cross-national study covering the years 1976–1993. International Studies Quarterly 43: 291–313.
Saideman SM, Ayres RW (2008) For Kin or Country: Xenophobia, Nationalism, and War. New York: Columbia University Press.
Salehyan I (2009) Rebels Without Borders: Transnational Insurgencies in World Politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Sarkees MR, Wayman F (2010) Resort to War, 1816–2007. Thousand Oaks: Sage, CQ Press.
Senese PD, Vasquez JA (2008) The Steps to War. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Simmons BA (1999) Territorial Disputes and Their Resolution: The Case of Ecuador and Peru. Washington DC: United State Institute of Peace.
State Department, United States (1995) Uganda Human Rights Practices, 1994. Country Reports on Human Rights Practices. Available at: https://www.refworld.org/country,COI,USDOS,UGA,3ae6aa3d24,0.html (accessed 20 November 2019)
State Department, United States (1996) Ecuador Human Rights Practices, 1995. Country Reports on Human Rights Practices. Available at: https://www.refworld.org/docid/3ae6aa390.html, (accessed 20 November 2019)
State Department, United States (1997a) Eritrea Human Rights Practices, 1996. Country Reports on Human Rights Practices. Available at: https://www.refworld.org/docid/3ae6aa228.html (accessed 20 November 2019)
State Department, United States (1997b) Sudan Human Rights Practices, 1996. Country Reports on Human Rights Practices. Available at: https://www.refworld.org/docid/3ae6aa3038.html (accessed 20 November 2019)
State Department, United States (1997c) Uganda Human Rights Practices, 1996. Country Reports on Human Rights Practices. Available at: https://www.refworld.org/docid/3ae6aa83c.html (accessed 20 November 2019)
Trumbore PF (2003) Victims or aggressors? Ethno-political rebellion and the use of force in militarized interstate disputes. International Studies Quarterly 47: 183–201.
Vasquez JA (1983) The tangibility of issues and global conflict: A test of Rosenau’s Issue Area Typology. Journal of Peace Research 20: 179–192.
Vasquez JA (1993) The War Puzzle. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Vasquez JA, Henehan MT (2001) Territorial Disputes and the Probability of War, 1816–1992. Journal of Peace Research 38: 123–138.
Vasquez JA, Mansbach RW (1984) The role of issues in global co-operation and conflict. British Journal of Political Science 14: 411–433.
Wallace GPR (2013) International law and public attitudes toward torture: An experimental study. International Organization 67: 105–140.
Weeks JLP (2014) Dictators at War and Peace. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Wood RM (2008) ‘A Hand Upon the Throat of a Nation?’: Economic Sanctions and State Repression, 1976–2001. International Studies Quarterly 52: 489–513.
Wood RM, Gibney M (2010) The Political Terror Scale (PTS): A Re-introduction and a Comparison to CIRI. Human Rights Quarterly 32:367–400.
Wood RM, Wright TM (2016) Responding to catastrophe: Repression dynamics following rapid-onset natural disasters. Journal of Conflict Resolution 60: 1446–1472.
Wright TM (2014) Territorial revision and state repression. Journal of Peace Research 51: 375–87.
Wright TM, Moorthy S (2018) Refugees, economic capacity, and host state repression. International Interactions 44: 132–155.

Cite article

Cite article

Cite article

OR

Download to reference manager

If you have citation software installed, you can download article citation data to the citation manager of your choice

Share options

Share

Share this article

Share with email
EMAIL ARTICLE LINK
Share on social media

Share access to this article

Sharing links are not relevant where the article is open access and not available if you do not have a subscription.

For more information view the Sage Journals article sharing page.

Information, rights and permissions

Information

Published In

Article first published online: January 9, 2020
Issue published: March 2020

Keywords

  1. Repression
  2. international conflict
  3. human rights
  4. militarized interstate dispute
  5. conflict

Rights and permissions

© The Author(s) 2020.

Authors

Affiliations

Thorin M. Wright
School of Politics and Global Studies, Arizona State University, United States of America

Notes

Thorin M. Wright, Associate Professor, School of Politics and Global Studies, Arizona State University, P.O. Box 873902, Tempe, Arizona 85287, United States of America. Email: [email protected]

Metrics and citations

Metrics

Journals metrics

This article was published in International Area Studies Review.

VIEW ALL JOURNAL METRICS

Article usage*

Total views and downloads: 1095

*Article usage tracking started in December 2016


Altmetric

See the impact this article is making through the number of times it’s been read, and the Altmetric Score.
Learn more about the Altmetric Scores



Articles citing this one

Receive email alerts when this article is cited

Web of Science: 2 view articles Opens in new tab

Crossref: 2

  1. International Conflict Involvement, Domestic Repression, and the Escal...
    Go to citation Crossref Google Scholar
  2. External Threats, Capacity, and Repression: How the Threat of War Affe...
    Go to citation Crossref Google Scholar

Figures and tables

Figures & Media

Tables

View Options

View options

PDF/ePub

View PDF/ePub

Get access

Access options

If you have access to journal content via a personal subscription, university, library, employer or society, select from the options below:


Alternatively, view purchase options below:

Purchase 24 hour online access to view and download content.

Access journal content via a DeepDyve subscription or find out more about this option.